Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges
In all probability, in the foreseeable future, spatial mobility will remain an important characteristic of stock breeding in many arid environments. The general trend in pastoralists’ development will be connected with the growing commercialization of production, introduction of modern livestock tec...
Gespeichert in:
Datum: | 2007 |
---|---|
1. Verfasser: | |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | English |
Veröffentlicht: |
Інститут сходознавства ім. А. Ю. Кримського НАН України
2007
|
Schriftenreihe: | Хазарский альманах |
Online Zugang: | http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/171569 |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
Назва журналу: | Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine |
Zitieren: | Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges / A.М. Khazanov // Хазарский альманах. — 2007. — Т. 6. — С. 240-258. — Бібліогр.: 92 назв. — англ. |
Institution
Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraineid |
irk-123456789-171569 |
---|---|
record_format |
dspace |
spelling |
irk-123456789-1715692020-09-27T01:25:01Z Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges Khazanov, A.М. In all probability, in the foreseeable future, spatial mobility will remain an important characteristic of stock breeding in many arid environments. The general trend in pastoralists’ development will be connected with the growing commercialization of production, introduction of modern livestock technology, the better definition of property rights, and, in some cases, even the introduction of private land tenure. Some pastoralists will benefit from This process will continue to be very painful, and will bring a lot of resentment. Perhaps, it is possible to somewhat alleviate its negative collateral effects, but hardly to avoid them completely. However, eventually mobile pastoralism should become more efficient and more productive along the lines of the capitalist economic efficiency. 2007 Article Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges / A.М. Khazanov // Хазарский альманах. — 2007. — Т. 6. — С. 240-258. — Бібліогр.: 92 назв. — англ. XXXX-0128 http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/171569 en Хазарский альманах Інститут сходознавства ім. А. Ю. Кримського НАН України |
institution |
Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine |
collection |
DSpace DC |
language |
English |
description |
In all probability, in the foreseeable future, spatial mobility will remain an important characteristic of stock breeding in many arid environments. The general trend in pastoralists’ development will be connected with the growing commercialization of production, introduction of modern livestock technology, the better definition of property rights, and, in some cases, even the introduction of private land tenure. Some pastoralists will benefit from This process will continue to be very painful, and will bring a lot of resentment. Perhaps, it is possible to somewhat alleviate its negative collateral effects, but hardly to avoid them completely. However, eventually mobile pastoralism should become more efficient and more productive along the lines of the capitalist economic efficiency. |
format |
Article |
author |
Khazanov, A.М. |
spellingShingle |
Khazanov, A.М. Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges Хазарский альманах |
author_facet |
Khazanov, A.М. |
author_sort |
Khazanov, A.М. |
title |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges |
title_short |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges |
title_full |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges |
title_fullStr |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges |
title_full_unstemmed |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges |
title_sort |
contemporary pastoralism: old problems. new challenges |
publisher |
Інститут сходознавства ім. А. Ю. Кримського НАН України |
publishDate |
2007 |
url |
http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/171569 |
citation_txt |
Contemporary Pastoralism: Old Problems. New Challenges / A.М. Khazanov // Хазарский альманах. — 2007. — Т. 6. — С. 240-258. — Бібліогр.: 92 назв. — англ. |
series |
Хазарский альманах |
work_keys_str_mv |
AT khazanovam contemporarypastoralismoldproblemsnewchallenges |
first_indexed |
2025-07-15T07:24:17Z |
last_indexed |
2025-07-15T07:24:17Z |
_version_ |
1837696819521388544 |
fulltext |
Anatoly м . Kha;
C O N T E M P O R A R Y P A S T O R A L IS M : O L D P R O B L F M o
C H A L L E N G E S
I will start with terminology because it is sometimes confusing and
and results in the wrong conclusions. One should discriminate between the n miSleaclin9,
nomadism, which, as some scholars claim, is coming to its end (H u m p h reyariPas,0fal
1999), other forms of traditional, subsistence-oriented moDile pastoralism, a n d n Snealh
mobility in general that is characteristic of many various forms of stock-breedinas,0raiist
as they utilize natural pastures (Khazanov 1994: 85 ff ).
In accordance with some not very precise estimates, there are still
million people in the world for whom mobile pastoralism remains the main
activity. They are living mainly in Africa, in the extended Middle East, in Central
Asia, in South Asia, and in the Far North. Besides, industrialized and
about 40
econom ic
an d Inner
c o m m erc ializedranch stock-breeding is practicing in the USA, Australia, New Zealand, Argentina, and few
other countries. In some countries, such as Niger, Djibouti or Somalia, mobile pastoralists
still constitute the majority of population; in many others they constitute a significant
minority. Thus, in Mongolia, a country with a population of 2 .5 million people, ab o u t 40 0
000 thousand people are pastoralists. while a half of the population directly or indirectly
depends on pastoralism (Fernandez-Gim enez 1999: 4). A remarkable resilience of mobile
pastoralism, despite numerous gloomy predictions to the contrary, is not accidental
indeed.
Climate and environment are not subject even to our post-industrial civilization It
is worth keeping in mind that pastoralism was originally developed as an alternative to
cultivation in the regions where the latter was impossible, or economically less profitable
In many of these areas the situation remains basically the same In Mongolia, pastures
constitute 74. 8 percent of the total area, while arable lands only 0, 8 percent. In
Kazakhstan, the ratio is 68, 8 and 12, 9 percent; in Turkmenistan, 61. 6 and 3, 0 percent,
in Kyrgyzstan, 42, 9 and 7, 2 percent. In Sudan, only one third of the land is potentially
arable In sub-Saharan Africa in general, the arid zone accounts for 37 percent, andthe
semi-arid zone for 18 percent of its land area (Jahnke 1982). Thus, mobile stock-breeding
may retain some advantages in comparison with other forms of economic activity
remain a rational and sustainable system for utilizing natural resources in the ar,d
semi-arid zones. Moreover, new ecological thinking holds that in many dry zo
pastoralism is more environmentally benign than cultivation. ljsm
Still, one must admit that, at present, traditional, subsistence oriented pasto ̂
is experiencing many difficulties and has to adjust to the new realities. Our times ar jng
called the "age of globalization", but globalization is just a new stage in the orvg ^
modernization process. To avoid any misunderstanding I would like to m ho|d
clarification W hen I write about modernization I do not imply simplistic views w i {epea i
that the developing non-Western countries should copy the Western models an based
the W estern stages of development. I perceive modernization as economic gr° cU|tural
on technological innovations with corresponding changes of socio-political an_____ ^
— .. Международный центр х<п<*РоН̂ * jjjS j
к | would also add that, as the world practice has demonstrated time and again,
J and long-term modernization, especially in our age of the transnationalization
llion, production and finance, is inseparably linked to the market economy and
!oroperty. All other ways of modernization eventually lead to the d e a d -e n d j
Г However, it is difficult for traditional economies not only to compete with, but even
— ing to the modern economies. Therefore, it is difficult, in principle, to maintain
mobile pastoralism within the contemporary, increasingly globalized economic
[ it is evident that traditional pastoralism should be somehow modernized. The
1 problem, however, is how to do this in the least painful way for pastoralists
~s
There no general recipes applicable to all individual situations, which is not
considering a great variety of ecological, socio-political, and economic
.5 o f pastoralists in different countries and in different parts of the world. Still, it is
to note that two major and radical solutions of modernization of traditional
alists that up to now have been suggested and experimented with, in many cases
I up to be inadequate
j The first solution was the communist one It was based on nationalization and/or
svization of the stock and pastureland accompanied by forced sedentarization of the
alists. In its extreme form: collectivization plus sedentarization, this model was, first,
J in the Soviet Union, in the late 1920s and in the early 1930s. Later, some other
fries adopted the whole model, or more often, either its collectivization or
ntarization parts: Iran, in the 1930s; Mongolia, in the 1950s; China, in the 1960s,
j i a , in the 1970s; Eritrea, in the 1990s. Generally, this method was a failure, i f
J j It is true that in the communist countries pastoralist production process was
^ewhat modernized, but this was done in their characteristically inefficient and
ju s way. Livestock breeding had lost its traditional character, but it was never
iized on the rational principles of modern economy. In the late communist period.'the
i goal was to increase the stock number by any means This should not be surprising
u, since even in Mongolia urban dwellers suffered chronic shortages of milk and
products (Fernandez-G im enez 1999:19)
However, an increase in the stock numbers was achieved by large subsidies, a
“ rd of the production cost, and, especially, of rapidly deteriorating environment Vast
of fertile pastures in Kazakhstan and Turkmenistan have been turned into sand
; other pastures were rapidly degrading In Kyrgyzstan, overgrazing resulted in
lation of 1, 7 million hectares of pastureland (according to some data, even 3, 5
n hectares), while another 30 percent of pastures lost their productivity (Dzoldoshev
i-J7: 168. Kliashtornyi 1999: 61), In Uzbekistan, more than 30 percent of pastures in the
and semi-desert zones are in various stages of degradation (Aripov 1997: 139) In
J p n g . salinization and desiccation affected about 4 , 7 million hectares (Benson and
vanberg 1998: 141), while the average productivity of rangeland has fallen by 30
p c e n t since the 1960s (Banks 1999: 298).
. Besides, all pastoralist activities were put under everyday control and supervision
aPP°inted managerial staff, which denied any initiative on the part of pastoralists
mselves The lack of personal responsibility and stimuli made the work of shepherds
■ 9 and uninspiring, while narrow specialization within appointed groups brought about
2 4 2
the loss of the whole complex of pastoralist skills. Those who are lamenting the dissoh t
of state and collective farms in the countries, like Mongolia or Kazakhstan, claim that t П
was done for political reasons. They prefer policies which are pursued by the th's
authoritarian countries, Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, where the collectives were™081
disbanded but only "reformed" (Sneath 2002: 174, Kerven 2003. 14 ff ). However th °l
fail to notice that this also was done for political reasons. Their other claim, that thV
conditions for pastoral households in the latter countries are still better than
Kazakhstan and Mongolia, remain unsubstantiated and raises many doubts. In
It is true, however, that post-communist period is marked everywhere by ma
negative developments in the pastoralist sector. One of the most striking characteristics of
the current situation in the region is that in its main stock-raising countries. Kazakhstan 1
and Kyrgyzstan, as well as in the Russian North, pastoralist specialization has become
unprofitable to the majority of households and farms due to the high input prices
undeveloped market channels, and low prices for animal production. Other conspicuous
characteristics are a serious decrease in the stock number, which was somewhat
stabilized only in the last few years, and the decrease in pastoralist mobility. These
negative developments were mainly the result of the state s premature retreat from its
former role as a provider of subsidies, credits, and input-supply systems, which was
accompanied by widespread corruption and em bezzlement (Khazanov et al. 1997,
Khazanov et al, 1999, Khazanov and Shapiro, 2005, Kerven, 2003).
In the beginning of the 1990s, some scholars from Central Asia and other
countries predicted the revival of traditional forms of mobile pastoralism in the region So
far, nothing like this has happened. Communal forms of land tenure and pasture utilization
destroyed in the Soviet period are not restored, and the role of kinship-based ties in the
organization of pastoralist production remains insignificant. At the same time, the
transition to market-oriented forms of pastoralism and animal husbandry is also blocked
for the majority of pastoralists. There is the danger of re-peasantization and even
pauperization of the majority of those who remain in the pastoralist sector. Instead of
becoming small-scale but efficient market-oriented producers, these people may be
locked into the role of subsistence-oriented non-capitalist holders
Another solution advocated mainly by some experts from Western countries is
iransformation of traditional pastoralists into commercial stock producers (Ingold 1978:
121), or even into capitalist ranch-owners. However, their recommendations did not take
nto account the environmental and social conditions in many Third World countries. The
anch system that emerged in the United States and in some other countries during the
second half of the 19m and in the first half of the 20th centuries was by no means a result
>f the development of the traditional pastoralist economies. Rather, it was created an
ntroduced anew
From the outset, the ranch system was aimed at production of l'vest0gS
ixclusively for sale and wag operating within profit-oriented market economies. There wa
о introductory period of subsistence production. Ranchers might, and still may, enj У
leir peculiar subculture, life-style and the quality of life, which for them were more '
юпеу, but they could not survive without having been market oriented and ProduCiri?.ets
rofit. In the beginning, the rapid growth of the East Coast and European beef w a r
uaranteed cattlemen high prices and profits, especially after the introductio
Междуна/юдный центр хизаро
сведения
2 4 3
lerator cars, in 1869, and refrigerated ships, in 1875. Stock owners were
not infrequently absentee cattle barons, who possessed capital,
Jnological know-how, and means to develop the intensive system of fenced ranching
fl irrigated pastures, machinery, motorized transport, tame-seed forage plants, selective
jd ing and artificial insemination, sheiters for animals in the winter, and so on (Dale
jo, Atherton 1961, Bennett 1985, Barsh, 1990, Jordan ,1993, Starrs, 1998). But today
n in the USA many family-owned ranches are facing growing difficulties and have but
d profitability. It is hard to them to compete with the giant agro-industrial enterprises.
W use relatively cheap grain and agricultural by-products to feed cattle Nowadays, it
rstill cheaper to ship animals to the feed by trucks, trains, ship, and even by planes, than
^deliver feed to animals (Shields and Mathews 2003). Besides, contemporary ranchers
sdentary people, and often their cattle are for the most part stationarary
In the short run, it would be unrealistic to expect similar developments in many
d World countries, where the relative costs of labor versus capital are unlikely to be
jstent with large-scale, capital intensive operations. This is why many scholars are
•«ating now much more gradual transformation of traditional pastoralism. In fact one
j already single out three stages in its attempted development. In the beginning, the
i ln attention had been paid to the technological improvements in stock-breeding within
в framework of traditional pastoralist social organization and land tenure. In other words,
jlstock development had taken priority over pastoralists' development
However, the real world is often quite a different place from the one assumed by
e development experts who had supposed that appropriate technological inputs would
tnatically yield desirable economic and social outputs. As Gorse and Steeds (1987:
[1 0 ) noted "Planners have often misunderstood the logic of traditional production systems.
|j have thereby overestimated the ease with which improvements could be introduced
q underestimated the negative consequences of intended improvements ’.
1 Many early developmental projects in Africa had failed or resulted in unforeseen
lercussions because administrators and planners ignored the peculiarities of the social
“ ’"'.ation and land tenure of pastoralists. Thus, attempts at intensifying traditional
fetoralism by implying modern technologies not infrequently gave rise to overstocking,
[grazing, degradation of vegetation, soil, and water, and even to desertification (see.
(r example, Reining 1978, Goldschmidt 1981: 104 f f , Handule and Gay, 1987, Bernus,
[9 9 0 166-167).
Later, in the 1970s and in the early 1980s, an understanding cam e that it would be
( difficult to introduce effective innovations without the general changes in social
‘ ns. The World Bank, the FAO, the European Union, the USAID, and other donors,
iarently influenced by the 'tragedy of commons’ theory (Hardin 1968: 1243-1248,
Sdin and Baden 1977, cf. Harden, 1988) began to promote individualized land tenure,
tsuming that it would be more efficient and productive than communal one (Fratkin
P997). This theory, which is still extremely influential in China (Banks 1999: 300), holds
"“fat if a resource belongs to everybody, nobody is interested in its preservation; therefore,
^ t io n s where stock is privately owned but pastures are in common property inevitably
N»t in overgrazing In fact, this theory is wrong because it has failed to take into
p o u n t a plethora of ethnographic data on pastoralists and does not distinguish between
Юзарский альманах".
2 4 4
an open access to pastures and their communal tenure, sometimes with furth
regulations (M cCay and Acheson 1987, Berkes et al 1989, Paine 1994: 187-188). 6r
No wonder that the new trend in the development policy has brought, at be
ambiguous results. The traditional pastoralists usually lack both the experience and th
necessary capital to start market-oriented ranch enterprises. It is not surprising that th6
development of capital-intensive livestock production, and sometimes speculatiy6
investments, usually led to a concentration of benefits in only a few hands (Waters-Bavp6
and Bayer 1992: 4). r
Commodification of livestock and labor resulted in the emergence of absente
herd owners and hired herders. Thus, in Turkey, Iran. Kenya, Tanzania, Botswana, some
W est African countries, and several others, it is not pastoralists but sedentary
businessmen with managerial experience and people with good connection in the
governments who have established commercial enterprises (see, for example, Bates
1980: 125 ff. on Turkey. Beck 1980, and Bradbury 1980 on Iran, Pelican 2002 on
Cameroon, Little 1985, Galaty 1992, Ellwood 1995 9 on Kenya, Arhem 1985 on
Tanzania, Hinderink and Sterkenburg 1987 on Botswana, Maliki 1986 on Niger, Salih
1990a on Sudan, and W aters-Bayer 1988 on Nigeria). Even the advocates of ranch
schemes admit that concentration of large tracts of land in the hands of but few individuals
creates a new set o f social and political problems (see, for example, Awogbade 1 987 25-
6 ).
This inevitably leads to an increasing number of displaced and unemployed
persons who, in the currently prevailing conditions in many developing countries, are often
denied viable possibilities for adjustment and alternative employment. At the same time, at
present, the pastoralist systems in Africa, as well as in some other parts of the world, are
no longer capable of reabsorbing destitutes without help from the outside sources, which,
at best, are insufficient and often inefficient, and, at worst, are non-existent
Only recently are some scholars and experts coming to the conclusion that
modernization of traditional pastoralists can not be taken in isolation from the broader
political and developmental issues. There are two main obstacles that hinder successful
modernization of traditional pastoralists. The first one is connected with their growing
political weakness and subjugated positions in many post-colonial states. These states
remain alien to the pastoralists. The latter cannot escape them, as they were sometimes
capable of doing in the past, but they do not benefit from the state either When they are
running away from the state as the pastoralists of Madagascar have literally tried to do in
the quite recent past (Kaufmann 1998), the state is running after them; and the state is
much stronger
The second obstacle consists in double marginalization of the pastoralists. They
are becoming increasingly marginalized within national systems of Third World countries,
which, in turn, are marginalized within regional and global economic systems. These
countries are often euphemistically called the developing’ ones; however, in fact, rnan ĥ°t
them especially in Africa and in some parts of the Middle East, are not developingi bu
stagnating. In all, the pastoralists have to adjust to external forces of great magm u
which are beyond their control. xt
In some respects, the colonial period was easier for pastoralists than the n
one. It is true that they lost their political independence, that colonial power confis
2 4 5
ie of their lands, regulated their migratory routes, and forced them to pay taxes,
/ever, som e exceptions notwithstanding, in general, those powers were often satisfied
with the maintenance of order and did not intentionally try to undermine the traditional way
■ nfe and social organization of the pastoralists.
In the post-colonial period, many national governments and ruling elites
Uionstrate much stronger anti-pastoralist bias (Azarya 1996: 69 ff., Manger 2001: 29).
)>ey consider the pastoralists as not sufficiently productive, and, at the same time, as a
jsruptive and unruly elem ent that has to be pacified and domesticated. In 1973, when the
__ahel was affected by a severe drought and many pastoralists lost their stock, Ebrahim
onate, at that time the Secretary of the Permanent African Interstate Committee for
jght Control, expressed his satisfaction with the situation with remarkably cynical
He stated: "We have to discipline these people, and to control their grazing and
}ir movements. Their liberty is too expensive for us. Their disaster is our opportunity"
Marnham 1979: 9). Terms, like "YdrClk", in Turkey, or "Kuchi", in Afghanistan, have
;ome derogatory labels. Pastoralists in China to this very day are often portrayed as
jnorant. irrational, backward, lazy, uncooperative, destructive to the environment, and
jsisting modernization (Williams 1997: 334 ff.). The governments of some Central Asian
buntries are glorifying their “nomadic.heritage", but are doing very little, if anything at all,
о assist their pastoralist in practice. No wonder that in many countries, pastoralists are
Currently facing more threats to their way of life than ever before in their long history.
Population growth, industrial development, and urbanization result in the
encroachment of sedentary populations into territories occupied by the pastoralists This is
often encouraged by the national governments. Not only in Central Asia, but in such
mtries as Nigeria, Mali, Cameroon. Ethiopia, Sudan, Kenya. Syria, Israel, Turkey. Iran,
ndia, China (especially in Inner Mongolia and Xinjiang) many pasturelands were
appropriated by the state, or were simply seized by agriculturalists to be put under the
plow (Lewis 1987, Galaty and Johnson 1990, Galaty and Bonte 1991, Koehler-Rolleson
1992, Smith 1992. Ma 1993: 173, Sheehy 1993: 17-30, Abu-Rabi'a 1994 15, Galaty et
I, 1994, Medzini 1998, Benson and Svanberg 1998: 141, Zaal 1999: 98-101)
In Nigeria, in 1957, 67 percent of the land was utilized as pastures; by 1986, the
irritory of pastureland decreased to 39 percent (Gefu and Gelles 1990: 39, 40). Even in
(ongolia, according to some estimates, between 1957 and 1994, the total grazing area
ias been reduced from 140 to 125 million hectares for urbanization purposes, tilling,
extension of roads and steppe tracks, etc. (Szynkiewicz 1998: 208). In the Scandinavian
id Russian Arctic, many pasturelands utilized by reindeer were lost to hydroelectric
development, extractive industries, and other projects (Morris 1990, Vakhtin 1992, Paine
11994. Krupnik 1998). Not infrequently, herding lands are also lost to gam e parks and
I urban areas (Anderson and Grove 1987, Kaufmann 1998: 136-137, Chatty 2001, Lenhart
jand Casimir, 2001: 10 ff., Rao, 2002). In addition, pastoralists face increasing dislocation
| brought about by droughts, famines, banditry, conflicts, and civil wars.
Many national governments and governmental agencies force the pastoralists to
|sedentarize. Actually, the allegedly permanent battle between the desert and the sown is
'an oversimplification of a great variety of real situations and is profoundly ahistorical
[Nevertheless, already in 1979, the Fifteenth International African Seminar held at Ahmady
:Bello University made a remarkable statement: “The conference notes that the nomadic
хазарский альманах", там 6. Харьков. 200/ ~
aspect of the life of pastoralists is no longer tenable in the face of ever greater pressu
land, and that it is not in the interests of the pastoralists themselves to continue to i ГеСг*
nomadic or semi-nomadic way of life'1 (Adamu and Kirk-Greene 1986: XVII, sepea<la
Khogali 1980, and Salih 1990: 64 ff.). The Chinese government is still pursuing a Dq i als°
settling down pastoralist peoples in Xinjiang (Benson and Svanberg 1998: 80, 146 1 вп'0?
In principle, sedentarization and urbanization of at least a part of m
pastoralists is inevitable and even desirable under contemporary conditions, if it Cha ^
the surplus labor in the pastoralist sector into other occupational activities. It may nnels
facilitate an increase of economic efficiency of those who will remain involved in ггЛ,6*1
pastoralism. However, at present, sedentarization of pastoralists confronts rn
difficulties, such as shortage of land suitable for cultivation, demographic pressure, etc7
is very difficult to turn to cultivation when arable land is already occupied by other peoni
who are numerically and politically stronger. As a result, the pastoralists often have Г
sedentarize in marginal areas, where cultivation is risky and unpredictable to the extern
that the sedentaries themselves consider such lands of little use for cultivation
Thus, at present, sedentarization can hardly be considered a general solution for
the majority of pastoralists. As Salzman (1980: V II) aptly remarked. "Sedentarization
viewed as an inevitable and necessary step in furthering progress and advancing
civilization, and pressed upon nomadic peoples by external forces, can have detrimental
consequences not only for the nomadic peoples themselves but for the large societies of
which they are part". Likewise, for a growing number o f pastoralists who are moving into
the cities and become urbanized, the problem of an employment is quite acute in many
countries.
In the past, pastoralist economies were never deliberately profit-oriented or
consistently aimed at meeting market demands, although they almost always had a barter
exchange or even a market component. Nowadays, the pastoralists, whether they like it or
not, are increasingly becoming involved in state, regional or international systems based
on a monetary economy with a corresponding shift from use-value to exchange-value and
commoditization of livestock and its products. At the same time, their engagement with the
market is proceeding in unfavorable conditions of state intervention and expanding world
markets
Products of animal husbandry from the developed countries are dominant on the
world markets, and it is very difficult for the pastoralist produce in the developing countries
to compete with them. Moreover, export produce from the developed countries has seiZ®
a significant share of the markets in some developing countries, while the Pastoral(she
there face many difficulties in selling their own produce. If one visited supermarkets m
major cities of Kazakhstan, in the 1990s, one would find a great variety of meat, saus g ̂
cheese, and even butter produced in Australia, New Zealand, the countries о ^
European Union, almost everywhere, except Kazakhstan. The local produce wa grs
mainly in bazaars. The situation began to change for better only in the last щ
M any milk products and other foodstuff in Mongolia are imported from other ^ |jng of
the second half of the 1980s and in the early 1990s, European Community du ssed
low-grade industrial beef, pork and offal on coastal W est African marketf haha 1996
demand for Sahelian fresh beef and small ruminant meat (Holtzman and Kuli
K a i) - Most m i,k Proc|u c ts available in Cameroon are imported from European countries
Regionally produced on the basis of imported products (Pelican 2002).
This situation contains an almost ironical side. W hile many international agencies,
Г the World Bank, are arguing that in Third World countries agriculture, including
I ^ ! toralism, should be self-sustainable, in all developed countries they are enjoying direct
4 jp d ire c t subsidies and other support by the governments and/or consumers. However,
L should take into account .that in the developed countries only a small percentage of
^ population is involved in agriculture, while in the developing countries the
■bjculturalists constitute more than a half o f population
In some countries, the price control and policies exercised by national
iments are unfavorable to the pastoralists even with regard to the local markets In
jhina since the 1980s, comparative price advantages have moved in favor of crop
K jjc t io n relative to animal husbandry (Williams 1997: 346) In 1998, in Mongolia, m eat
;less than a third of its value in terms of flour, in 1990 (Sneath 2002: 172). Prices on
It in Africa in general a re artificially low (John Galaty, personal communication).
I Besides, subsidies by themselves far from always change the situation for better
,really assist the development. I can refer to the example of some Arab countries,
dally the oil-producing ones. They support the Bedouin in the form of money
u^nts. land allocations, job offers in the military and administration, and so on. As the
lit of this policy, many people moved into other sectors of national economies and
es.
O ne might expect that this would facilitate modernization of pastoralism and
Mtion of its production. Nothing like this has happened, however. It seems that in
в « . 0e subsidies and subventions serve not as incentives for development but rather as
S en s a tio n for a lack of development. There are but few ranch and commercial stock
i n g enterprises in those countries which are unable to satisfy their needs
R e lay s , countries, like Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Oman, Lybia, and even Jordan, have to
у upon imported m eat and even dairy foodstuff (see, for example, Katakura 1977, Cole
181, Fabietti 1982, Lancaster and Lancaster 1986, Kostiner 1990: 244 ff on Saudi
i; Scholz 1981; Jansen 1986 on Oman; Behnke 1980 on Libya; Abu Jaber and
jaraibeh 1981, Hiatt 1984 on Jordan).
One may complain about unfair competition and about limited export opportunities
W je developing countries as much as one wants, but this is how the things are in
^ tic e , at the moment. To provide but one of many possible examples I can refer to the
Jeolian case. As far as I know, cashmere is the only product of animal husbandry that
f country successfully exports to the world markets. Moreover, while the developed
Jtintries build various barriers, like rigorous quality constrains, which prevent the import
M n im a l products from the developing countries, the governments of the latter, not
^B Jently , encourage the import and control producer and consumer prices to keep
n on the lower level for the growing urban population.
So far, I have talked about various schemes suggested and implemented by
g r -s , experts on development, and government officials. But what about social
J p s ts , especially anthropologists? in many cases we were sitting on the fence
B ja in in g about the decay of traditional pastoralism but having been unable to offer a
p © and practical alternative. Perhaps, this attitude was the best expressed by Baxter
Международный центр **Рскнй альманах” . ■ ■■2
I
(1987: I): "...A lmost all, indeed maybe all, the development Interventions to date had n
helped the impoverished pastoralists at all, nor had they added a cent to the wealth of a
nation”. This opinion is echoed by Scoones (1996: 3): 'The last 30 years have seen th^
unremitting failure of livestock development projects across Africa, Millions of dollars ha 6
been spent with few obvious returns and not a little damage Most commentators a o /6
that the experience has been a disaster, so much so that many donors and oth 6
international agencies have effectively abandoned the dry zone in their developme^
efforts"
It should not be surprising then that attempts at dialog between anthropologists
and developers and governmental officials so far was not very fruitful. When
administrators and planners began to advance and implement the schemes aimed at
transformation of traditional pastoralists into commercial livestock producers, this brought
them into direct conflicts with the majority in anthropological community Thus, we pointed
out time and again that our opponents did not realize that production is not only an
economic activity; it is also a socially and culturally constructed activity
I must confess that in the past I also was very critical of many development
projects suggested by various international organizations and implemented by national
governments in Third World countries (see, for example, Khazanov 1998 12 ff ). I am still
critical of many those projects However, now I am coming to the conclusion that my
general attitude to the principle goal of advocated development, which I shared with many
other anthropologists, was, to some extent, unfair and unrealistic Explicitly or implicitly,
we the anthropologists, resent most development projects because they undermine those
types of social organization, culture, values, etc. that are connected with the traditional
pastoralism, Essentially, our criticism has a certain anti-modernist touch, although we
rarely admit this. Som e recommendations m ade by anthropologists, e.g. that "room should
be found on the rangelands for less fortunate people, if necessary at the expense of the
more fortunate' or that "government should encourage and support traditional
mechanisms for redistributing livestock so that the rich provide the poor with oasic
needs” (Baxter 1987: II) are well-intended indeed, but I wonder whether they are realistic.
One may agree with Sanford (1996: 179) that “we social scientists have not yet structured
our views rigorously enough to have any clear message for policy makers and
practitioners except that everything is very complex, that Hardin (1968) was wrong and
that livestock mobility is to be encouraged”
T h e opinion expressed by Raikes (1981: 250) more than twenty years ago tha
the most productive (or least destructive) way to incorporate mobile pastoralists in
national economies is "through developing the production and productivity of existl. -
herding systems r a t h e r than through their replacement by modern systems
unsubstantiated. The practice is teaching us the opposite. Traditional forms of soc
organization and of associated social behavior are often becoming c o u n t e r p r o d u c t iv e
inappropriate in the age bf globalization. -ve£j
It is true that so far mobile pastoralism in the developing countries has su
despite ail kinds of development schemes, rather than because of the,|nsm ^0т
development projects were ill-devised. Attempts at transforming mobile pastoiiJijgtflitive
above, initiated, designed and implemented by the state through purely adm'™ a \ and
measures in most of the cases have not brought the desired results In te rn a ti
Btional aid was sometimes directed at the wrong goals, misused and then was
feinaturely withdrawn. For example, in the 1990s, the assistance to African pastoralists
^"international agencies was much less than in the 1960s and in the 1970s The Soviet
и amounted to more than a third of annual G DP in Mongolia Its withdrawal was one of
^,e main reasons of the economic crisis in the country,
4 The sam e can be said about national assistance to and investment in pastoralist
Ic to r o f economies in rare cases, when it takes place at all. Thus, in China, only a
Ctatively small portion of agricultural development resources goes into improving
testock production. Even when the arid lands along its northern frontier manage to
Bract large investment capital, local herders are bypassed in the development process
Williams 1997: 346-347) In Mongolia, the level of investment in pastoralism is low and
I s declining steadily in the 1990s. The percentage of all bank loans granted to borrowers
btside the capital, Ulaanbaatar, has fallen each year throughout the nineties, from 46
bcent. in 1993, to 11 percent, in 1998 (Sneath 2002: 173)
ji In any case, excessive paternalism, even a benevolent one, will not help. The
rain problem is not w hat to do with the mobile pastoralists, but what the pastoralists have
L do themselves in order to cope with challenges of globalization. The pastoralists must
pcome full-fledged citizens of modernizing states and have a voice in decision-making,
hey should not only be listened to; they should directly be involved in the planning and
nplementation of development programs. At the sam e time, learning from the previous
K takes national governments and international agencies should do more by providing
Ю pastoralists with various kinds of input, education, water service, veterinary care
Bnsportation facilities, stock insurance, information, market infrastructure, credits, etc.
Some protectionist measures can not be excluded as well.
T jjv Only the future will tell whether these recommendations, and many similar ones,
emam wishful thinking, or not. Still, the general trend of transformation of mobile
estoralism in the 2 1 * century seems to m e quite clear and unavoidable Let us face the
ruth. In many countries, mobile pastoralism in its current forms is not a viable economic
lotion anymore In East Africa, in the Middle East, in Central Asia, and in the Russian
porth the inability of many pastoralists to subsist primarily on livestock-economy has
tecome a common theme
Modernization, which is highly beneficial in general, at the sam e time, was, is, and
Ml remain a merciless selection process. It is uneven and differential. It has its winners,
fs losers, and those whose awards are delayed. Those who fail to cope with it either
P *sh . or, at best, are relegated to the margins of the developed world. They will be
■Wed access to proper education, advanced medical service, the telecommunications
gjolution. a chance of improving their living standards, and many other benefits of
BM em ity because directly or indirectly these benefits are intrinsically connected with the
warket-oriented economy.
Щ ' Without modernization the mobile pastoralists face the risk of being further
■ftginalized and alienated, or of becoming "zoo groups", an exotic attraction for urban
2™antics and tounsts Contrary to Krupnik (2000 54), I am by no means sure that
[ a9ging public spirit and herders’ pride can be boosted via outreach and exhibit
^ B jjn w n e rs publication of elders narratives, historical photographs, catalogues and
passical ethnographies addressed primarily to local audiences". There is nothing wrong
ЧН'кин альманах” , том 6 Харьков. 2007
with this and other similar suggestions Besides, they help to keep anthropologists
occupied. But it would be very naive to expect them to really change the situation f0r
better
In order to continue being pastoralists people should benefit from their capability
of being pastoralists. It is indeed high time that anthropological concerns shift from a
concern for a 'way of life’ to a concern for the people who have to live it under dire
circumstances. Likewise, episodic revivals of more or less traditional pastoralism, in one
country or another, are more connected to temporary factors than with dominant trends in
contemporary development Thus, in Somalia this revival was connected with the
disintegration of the state, in Mongolia, in the early 1990s, it was connected with the
collapse of the communist command economy which resulted in a high unemployment
rates Modernization is an irresistible force, and there is no viable alternative to it. This is
w hat the antiglobalists do not want to comprehend.
In all probability, spatial mobility will remain an important characteristic of stock
breeding in many arid environments. The complete transformation of mobile pastoralists
into sedentary cultivators or town-dwellers would mean that vast desert and semi-desert
territories unsuitable for cultivation would cease to be used fcr food production and would
be left to lie as waste land Besides, it is worth to remember that crop cultivation is more
environmentally degrading than pasturing. Apparently, the general trend in pastoralists'
development will be connected with the growing commercialization and monetarising of
production, introduction of modern livestock technology, and other innovations. Probably,
one will witness the better definition of property rights, and, in some countries, even the
introduction of individual land tenure. One may only hope that the appropriate land tenure
arrangements will be flexible enough to adjust to environments, especially to non
equilibrium ones, which are characterized by high climatic variability. There is also a
danger of the substitution of long-term optimization for short-term maximization of
production
Modernization brings not only technological and economic changes, but social
and cultural changes as well. Some pastoralists will benefit from these developments, but
I am afraid, that many will find themselves at the losing end. These changes may increase
further the tension within pastoralist groups, which is already evident in many countries.
They may result in the erosion of many traditional social institutions, bonds, statuses,
values, loyalties, and authenticities, as well as in a growing economic inequality
Actually, these processes are already quite conspicuous in Africa (see, for
example, Bovin and Manger 1990) and other parts of the world. They may have other
disruptive consequences, since the mere destruction of the traditional forms of socia
organization will hardly bring a vital new system; on the contrary, this may result in socia
disorganization and dislocation In any case, more people will have to leave pastoralism
and to move into other Rectors of economy. In the worst scenario more pastoralists may
becom e destitutes, whose physical survival will depend on the international reie
organizations. ...
It is impossible to predict in detail what exact forms the integration of mo J
pastoralism in the developing countries into the globalized market will take. .^Р рагЛ гоГП
there will be various forms, including transitional ones, which may be quite differen ̂
each other in terms of land tenure, degree of specialization, and many other param
Международный центр хазар0****
|n all, this process will continue to be very painful, and will bring a lot of resentment
perhaps. it is possible to somewhat alleviate its negative collateral effects, but hardly tc
Lvoid them completely. However, hopefully, eventually mobile pastoralism will become
jpore competitive and more productive along the lines of capitalist economic effectiveness
Meanwhile, anthropologists and other social scientists will be able to write many more
j»ooks and articles critical of this development and blaming everybody and everything, o'
fcourse, except themselves, for the decay of traditional pastoralism
References
<№u Jaber, К S. and Gharaibeh, F.A. 1981. Bedouin Settlement: Organizational, Legal
and Administrative Structure in Jordan In: D. Aronson, J. D Gaiaty, and P. C. Salzm ar
[eds) T he F u tu re o f P a s to ra l P e o p le s . Ottawa: International Development Researcr
Centre: 294-300
kbu-Rabi'a, A. 1994 T h e N e g e v B e d u in a n d L iv e s to c k R e a r in g S o c ia l, E c o n o m ic anc
P o lit ic a l A s p e c ts Oxford: Berg Publishers.
Adamu, M. and Kirk-Greene, A.H.M. (eds ). 1986. P a s to ra l is ts o f th e W e s t A fr ic a r
S ava n n a . Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Anderson, D and Grove, R (eds ). 1987 C o n s e rv a tio n in A fr ic a : P e o p le , P o lic ie s a m
P ra c tice . Cambridge Cambridge University Press.
Arhem, К 1985 P a s to ra l M a n in th e G a rd e n o f E d e n : T h e M a a s a i o f th e N g o ro n g o rc
C o n s e rv a tio n A re a Uppsala: Uppsala Research Reports on Cultural Anthropology
Aripov, U. 1997 Karakulevodstvo i aridnoe kormoproizvodstvo v Uzbekistane: sostoiani<
I problemy razvitiia. In: A. Khazanov, V. Naumkin, and K. Shapiro (eds ). P a s to ra l is m ii
C e n tra l A s ia . Moscow: University of Wisconsin-Madison and Russian Center for Strategic
Research and International Studies: 134-141.
Atherton, L. 1961. The C a tt le K in g s . Bloomington: University of Indiana Press.
Awogbade, M. D. 1987 Grazing Reserves in Nigeria N o m a d ic P e o p le s (N S ) 23: 19-30
Azarya, V. 1996. N o m a d s a n d th e S ta te in A fr ic a : T h e P o lit ic a l R o o ts o f M a rg in a lity
Leiden: African Studies Centre.
fanks, T. 1999. State, Community and Common Property in Xinjiang: Synergy or Strife'
d e v e lo p m e n t P o l ic y R e v ie w 17: 293-313.
Barsh, R .L 1990. The Substitution of Cattle for Bison on the Great Plains. In: P A. Olson
(ed.). T h e S tru g g le fo r the L a n d : In d ig e n o u s In s ig h t a n d In d u s tr ia l E m p ire in th e S e m ia r id
W o rld Lincoln and London: The University of Nebraska Press: 103-126.
Bates, D.G. 1980. YOruk Settlement in Southeast Turkey. In: P C Salzman (ed.). W h e n
N o m a d s S e ttle : P ro c e s s e s o f S e d e n ta r iz a tio n a s A d a p ta tio n a n d R e s p o n s e N ew York
Praeger 124-139.
Baxter, P .T .W . 1987. Introduction. In: P. T. W . Baxter (ed.) P ro p e r ty , P o v e r ty a n d
P e o p le : C h a n g in g R ig h ts in P ro p e rty a n d P ro b le m s o f P a s to ra l D e v e lo p m e n t. Manchester
University of Manchester: l-VII
Beck, L. 1980 Herd Owners and Hired Shepherds The Qashqa'i of Iran. E th n o lo g y 19, 3.
327-352.
Behnke, R. 1980. T he H e rd e rs o f C y re n a ic a : E c o lo g y . E c o n o m y a n d K in s h ip a m o n g th e
B e d o u in o f E a s te rn L ib y a . Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Bennet, J.W . 1985. Range Culture and Society in the North American W est. F o lk lo re
A n n u a l: 88-104.
Benson, L. and Svanberg, I. 1998 C h in a 's L a s t N o m a d s . T h e H is to ry a n d C u ltu re o f
C h in a ’s K a z a k h s . Armonk, New York: M E. Sharpe.
Berkes, F., Feeny, D., McCay, В J ., and Acheson, J.M. 1989 The Benefits o f the
Commons. N a tu re 340: 91-93.
Bernus. E 1990. Dates, Dromedaries, and Drought: Diversification in Tuareg Pastoral
Systems. In: J.G .Galaty and D.L.Johnson (eds.). The W o rld o f P a s to ra l is m : H e rd in g
S y s te m s in C o m p a ra t iv e P e rs p e c tiv e . New York: Guilford Press
Bovin, M. and Manger, L. (eds.). 1990. A d a p t iv e S tra te g ie s in A f r ic a n A r id L a n d s
Uppsala: The Nordic Africa Institute.
Bradburd, D.A. 1980. Never Give a Shepherd an Even Break: Class and Labor among the
Komachi. A m e ric a n E th n o lo g is t 7, 4: 603-620.
Chatty, D. 2001. Pastoral Tribes in the Middle East and Wildlife Conservation Schemes:
The Endangered Spicies? N o m a d ic P e o p le s (N S) 5: 104-122.
Cole, D 1981. Bedouin and Social Change in Saudi Arabia. J o u rn a l o f A s ia n a n d A fr ic a n
S tu d ie s 16, 1-2: 128-149
Международный центр хичароаедення
Dale, E.E 1960 T he R a n g e C a ttle In d u s try : R a n c h in g o n th e G re a t P la in s f ro m 1 8 6 5 i
1925 . Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Dzoldoshev, K. 1997. Sostoianie pastbishch i probiemy proizvodstva i zagotovki
Kyrgyzstane. In: A Khazanov, V. Naumkin, and К Shapiro (eds.). P a s to ra l is m in C e n tr
A s ia . Moscow: University of Wisconsin-Madison and Russian Center for Strateg
Research and International Studies: 168-177.
Ellwood, W . 1995. Nomads at the Crossroads. N e w In te rn a tio n a lis t 266 {April): 7-10
Fabietti, U . 1982 Sedentarization as a M eans of Detribalization: Som e Policies of tl
Saudi Arabian Government towards the Nomads In; T Niblock (ed.). S ta te , S o c ie ty a i
E c o n o m y in S a u d i A ra b ia . London: Croom Helm
FernanaeZ'Gim enez, M E. 1999 Reconsidering the Role of Absentee Herd Owners:
View from Mongolia H u m a n E c o lo g y 27, 1: 1-27
Fratkin, E 1997. Pastoralism: Governance and Development Issues. A n n u a l R e v ie w
A n th ro p o lo g y 26. 235-261.
Gaiaty J. 1992. “The Land is Yours": Social and Economic Factors in the Privatizatic
Subdivision and Sale of M aasai Ranches. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 30: 26-40
Gaiaty, J. and Bonte, P. (e d s ). 1991. H e rd e rs , W a rr io rs , a n d T ra d e rs : P a s to ra l is m
A fr ic a Boulder W estview Press.
Gaiaty, J. G . and Johnson, D.L. (eds ). 1990. T h e W o r ld o f P a s to ra l is m : H erd .
S y s te m s in C o m p a ra t iv e P e rs p e c tiv e . N ew York: Guilford Press.
Gaiaty, J. G , Hjort a f Ornas, A., Lane, Ch., and Ndagala, D (e d s ). 1994. The Paste
Land Crisis: Tenure and Dispossession in East Africa. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 34/35 (spe<
issue).
Gefu, J O and Getles J.L 1990 Pastoralists, Ranchers and the State in Nigeria г
North America: A Comparative Analysis. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 25-27: 34-50.
Goldshmidt, W . 1981. The Failure of Pastoral Economic Development Programs in Afri
In J.G.Gataty, D.Aronson, and P.C .Saizman (eds ). T h e F u tu re o f P a s to ra l P eop .
Ottawa: International Developmental Research Centre: 101-118.
Gorse, J.E. and Steeds, D.R. 1987 D e s e r t i f ic a tio n in th e S a h e lia n a n d S u d a n ia n Z o n e ■
W e s t A fr ic a . Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Handule, A. and Gay, С W 1987. Development and Transitional Pastoralism in Som;
N o m a d ic P e o p le s 24: 36-43
2 5 4
Hardin, G. 1968. The Tragedy of the Commons. S c ie n c e 162; 1243-1248.
Hardin. G 1988. Commons failing N e w S c ie n tis t, 22 (October)
Hardin G. and Baden: J. 1977 M a n a g in g th e C o m m o n s . San Francisco: W H. Freeman.
Hiatt, J.M. 1984. State Formation and the Encapsulation of Nomads: Local Change and
Continuity among Recently Sedentarized Bedouin in Jordan. N o m a d ic P e o p le s , 15: 1-11.
Hinderink, J. and Sterkenburg. J J 1987. A g r ic u ltu ra l C o m m e rc ia l iz a tio n a n d G o v e rn m e n t
P o l ic y in A fric a . London and New York: KPI.
Holtzman, J.S. and Kulibaba. N.P. 1996. Livestock Marketing in Pastoral Africa: Policies to
Increase Competitiveness, Efficiency and Flexibility. In: I. Scoones (ed.) L iv in g w ith
U n c e r ta in ty . N e w D ire c t io n s in P a s to ra l D e v e lo p m e n t in A fr ic a . London. Intermediate
Technology Publications' 79-94
Ingold T. 1978. The Rationalization of Reindeer M anagem ent among Finnish Lapps.
D e v e lo p m e n t a n d C h a n g e , 1: 103-122.
Jahnke, H 1982. L iv e s to c k P ro d u c tio n S y s te m s a n d L iv e s to c k D e v e lo p m e n t in T ro p ica l
A fr ic a . Kiel: Kieler Wissenschaftverlag Vauk.
Jansen, J 1986 N o m a d s in th e S u lta n a te o f O m a n : T ra d it io n a n d D e v e lo p m e n t in D h o fa r
Boulder: Westview Press
Jordan, T G 1993. N o r th A m e ric a n C a tt le -R a n c h in g F ro n tie rs : O r ig in s , D iffu s io n a n d
D iffe re n t ia t io n Albuquerque, NM: University o f New-Mexico.
Katakura, M 1977. B e d o u in V illa g e : A S tu d y o f a S a u d i A ra b ia n P e o p le in T ra n s it io n
Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
Kaufmann, J. C. 1998. The Cactus W as Our Kin: Pastoralism in the Spiny Desert of
Southern Madagaskar In: J.Ginat and A .M Khazanov. C h a n g in g N o m a d s in a C h a n g in g
W o rld . Brighton: Sussex Academic Press: 124-142.
Kerven. C. (ed.). 2003 P ro s p e c ts f o r P a s to ra l is m in K a z a k h s ta n a n d T u rk m e n is ta n F ro m
S ta te F a rm s to P r iv a te F lo ck s . London and N ew York: RoudledgeCurzon
Kerven, C. 2003. Agrarian Reform and Privatization in the W ider Asian Region In: C.
Kerven (ed ). P ro s p e c ts fo r P a s to ra l is m in K a z a k h s ta n a n d U z b e k is ta n . F ro m S ta te
F a rm s to P r iv a te F lo c k s . London and New York: RoutlrdgeCurzon
Khazanov, A.M. 1994. Nomads a n d th e O u ts id e W o r ld . 2 nd ed. Madison: The University of
Wisconsin Press.
Международный центр хизиронсдсни*
Khazanov, A.M. 1998. Pastoralists in the Contemporary World: The problem of Survivs
In J Ginat and A. M. Khazanov (eds ). C h a n g in g N o m a d s in a C h a n g in g W o rld . Brightoi
Sussex Academic Press: 7-.23
Khazanov, A., Naumkin, V , and Shapiro, K. (eds.). 1997. P a s to ra l is m in C e n t ra l A s i
Moscow: University of Wisconsin - Madison and Russian Center for Strategic Researt
and International Studies.
Khazanov, A., Naumkin, V., Shapiro K., and Tomas, D. (e d s ). 1999. T h e K a za kh s * ;
L iv e s to c k S e c to r in T ra n s it io n to a F re e E c o n o m y . Moscow: University of Wisconsin
Madison and Russian Center for Strategic Research and International Studies.
Khazanov, A. and Shapiro, K. 2005. Contemporary Pastoralism in Centrai Asia. In:
Amitai and M. Biran (eds ). M o n g o ls , T u rk s a n d O th e rs : E u ra s ia n N o m a d s a n d t
S e d e n ta ry W o r ld Leiden: Bril!: 503-534.
Khogali, M .M . 1981 Sedentarization of the Nomads: Sudan In: O.Aronson, J.G Gals
P .С Saizman, and A. Chouinard (e d s } T he F u tu re o f P a s to ra l P e o p le s . Otta\
International Development Research Centre: 302-313.
Kliashtornyi, S. 1999 “Sel'skokhoziaistvennaia revoliutsiia’’ v Kyrgyzstane
predpolagaemye lendentsii daineishego razvitiia. In- A. Khazanov, V. Naumkin,
Shapiro, and D Thom as (eds.). T h e K a z a k h s ta n L iv e s to c k S e c to r in T ra n s it io n t
M a rk e t E c o n o m y . Moscow: University of Wisconsin-Madison and Russian Center
Strategic Research and International Studies: 60-70.
Koehlrer-Rollefson, L The Raika Dromedar Breeders in Rajasthan: A Pastoral Syster
Crisis. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 30: 74-83.
Kostiner, J. 1980 Transforming Dualities. Tribe and State Formation in Saudi Arabia
P S. Khoury and J. Kostiner (eds ). Tribes and State Formation in the Middle E
Berkeley: University of California Press: 226-251.
Krupnik, I. 1998. Understanding Reindeer Pastoralism in Modern Siberia: Ecoloi
Continuity versus State Engineering. In: J. G inat and A.M. Khazanov (ed s ). C h a r
nomads in a C h a n g in g W o rld . Brighton: Sussex Academic Press: 223-242.
Krupnik. I. 2000. Reindeer Pastoralism in Modern Siberia: Research and Survival D
the Tim e of Crash. P o la r R e s e a rc h 19 ,1 : 49-56.
Lancaster, W . and Lancaster, F. 1986. The Concept of Territory among the F
Bedouin. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 20: 41-48.
"Хазарский альманах” , том й Харьков. 200'
Lenhart. L. and Casimir, M.J 2001 Environment, Property Resources and the Slate: An
Introduction. N o m a d ic P e o p le s (N S) 5, 3: 6-20.
Lewis, N. N 1S87. N o m a d s a n d S e ttle rs in S y r ia a n d J o rd a n , 1 8 0 0 -1 9 8 0 . Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Little, P. 1985. Absentee Herd Owners and Part-Time Pastoralists. The Political Economy
of Resource Use in Northern Kenya. H u m a n E c o lo g y 13 . 2 :131 -151 .
Ma, R. 1993 Migrant and Ethnic Integration in the Process of Socio-Economic Change in
Inner Mongolia. A V illage Study. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 33: 173-191.
McCay, В. M. and Acheson, J M. (eds ). 1987. T he Q u e s t io n o f th e C o m m o n s : T he
C u ltu re a n d E c o lo g y o f C o m m u n a l R e s o u rc e s . Tucson: University of Arizona Press
Maliki, B. 1986. The Changing Structures of Livestock Ownership among Pastoralists in
Niger. B u lle t in o f the In s t itu te fo r D e v e lo p m e n t A n th ro p o lo g y ,4 ,1 : 3-5.
Manger, L. 2001. Pastoralist-State Relationships among the Hadendowa Beja of Eastern
Sudan. N o m a d ic P e o p le s (N S) 5 ,2 :2 1 -4 8 .
Marnham, P. 1979. N o m a d s o f th e S a h e l. London: Minority Rights Group Report 33.
Medzini, A. 1998. Bedouin Settlement Policy in Israel, 1964-1996. In: J.Ginat and A.M.
Khazanov (eds.). C h a n g in g N o m a d s in a C h a n g in g W o rld . Brighton: Sussex Academic
Press: 58-67.
Morris, C.P . 1990. Hydroelectric Development and the Human Rights of Indigenous
People. In: P.A.OIson {ed.). T h e S tru g g le fo r L a n d : In d ig e n o u s In s ig h t a n d In d u s tr ia l
E m p ire in th e S e m ia r id W o rld . Lincoln and London: University of Nebraska Press: 193-
209.
Paine, R. 1994. H e rd s o f th e T u n d ra : A P o r tra it o f S a a m i R e in d e e r P a s to ra l is m
W ashington and London: Smithsonian Institution Press, 1994
Pelican. M. 2002. From Cultural Property to M arket Goods: Changes in Economic
Strategies and Herd M anagem ent Rationales of Agro-Pastoral Fulbe in North W est
Cameroon. A paper submitted to the workshop "C o lle c t iv e a n d M u lt ip le F o rm s o f P ro p e r ty
in A n im a ls 11 held at the M ax Planck Instiute for Socia! Anthropology, Halle/Saale
Raikes, P.L, 1981. L iv e s to c k D e v e lo p m e n t a n d P o lic y in E a s t A fr ic a . Uppsala: The
Scandinavian Institute of African Studies.
Rao, A. 2002. Pastoral Nomads, the State and a National Park: the Case of Dachigam,
Kashmir. N o m a d ic P e o p le s (N S) 6,2: 72-98.
Между,
Reining, P (ed ). 1978 H a n d b o o k o r, D e s e r t i f ic a tio n In d ic a to rs Washington, [
American Association for the Advancement of Science.
Salih, M 1990. Agro-Pastoralists Response to Agricultural Policies The Predicame
the Baggara, Western Sudan. In. M. Bovin and L Manger (eds ). A d a p t iv e S tra te g y
A fr ic a n A r id L a n d s . Uppsala: The Scandinavian Institute of African Studies: 59-75.
Salih, M. 1990a Government Policy and Options in Pastoral Development in the S i
N o m a d ic P e o p le s 25-27: 65-78.
Salzman, P C. 1980. Preface. In: P.S. Salzman (ed.). W h e n N o m a d s S e tt le P ro c e s s
S e d e n ta r iz a tio n a s A d a p ta tio n a n d Response. New York: Praeger: V II-VIII.
Sandford, S 19S6. Improving the Efficiency of Opportunism: New Directions for Pa;
Development. In: I. Scoones (ed ). L iv in g w ith U n c e r ta in ty . N e w D ire c t io n s in P a :
D e v e lo p m e n t in A fr ic a . London: Intermediate Technology Publications 174-182.
Scholz, F. (ed ). 1981. B e d u in e n im Z e ic h e n d e s E rdO ls : S tu d ie n z u r E n tw ivk - 'u r
B e d u in is c h e n L e b e n s ra u m S u d o s t-A ra b ie n s . Wiesbaden: Dr. Ludwig Reichert Verlag
Scoones., 1 .1996. N ew Directions in Pastoral Development in Africa In: I. Scoones. i
w ith U n c e r ta in ty N e w D ire c t io n s in P a s to ra l D e v e lo p m e n t in A fr ic a . London: In ter mu
Technology Publications: 1-36.
Sheehy, D.P. 1993. Grazing M anagem ent Strategies as a Factor Influencing Ecol<
Stability o f Mongolian Grasslands. N o m a d ic P e o p le s 33 :17 -30 .
Shields, D A. and Mathews, K.H. 2003. Interstate Livestock Movements. Ecoi
Research Service Report. U S DA-LDP-M -108-01. Available 06/06/05
http:/www. ers.usda.gov/Data/lnterstateLivestockMovements.
Smith, A.B 1992 P a s to ra l is m in A f r ic a : O r ig in s a n d D e v e lo p m e n t E c o lo g y . Londo
Athens. Christopher Hurst and Ohio University Press.
Sneath, D. 2002. Producer Groups and the Decolectivization of the Mongolian Ps
Economy. In J. Heyer, F Stewart, and R. Thorp (eds ). G ro u p B e h a v io u
D e v e lo p m e n t. Is th e M a rk e t D e s t ro y in g C o o p e ra t io n ? Oxford: Oxford University
161-184.
Starrs, P F. 1998. L e t th e C o w b o y R id e : C a tt le R a n c h in g in th e A m e ric a n W e s t С /
th e N o r th A m e ric a n L a n d s c a p e Baltimore. John Hopkins University Press.
Szynkiewicz, S. 1998. Contemporary Mongol Concepts on Being a Past
Institutional Continuity, Change and Substitutes In: J.Ginat and A M Khazanov
C h a n g in g P a s to ra l is ts in a C h a n g in g W o rld Brighton: Sussex Academic Press: 202-
“ Хадерскии альманах", том 6. Ха/>ыс<
258 s = =
Vakhtin, N. 1992. Native Peoples of the Russian Far North. London; Minority Rights
Group.
Waters-Bayer, A. 1988. D a iry in g b y S e tt le d F u la n i A g ro p a s to ra lis ts in C e n tra l N ig e ria .
Kiel. Wissenschaftsverlag Vauk.
Waters-Bayer. A. and Bayer, W . 1992. The Roie of Livestock in the Rural Economy.
N o m a d ic P e o p le s 31 :3 -18
Williams, M 1997. The Desert Discourse of Modern China M o d e m C h in a 23, 3: 328-
355.
In all probability, in the foreseeable future, spatial mobility will remain an important
characteristic of stock breeding in many arid environments. The general trend in
pastoralists’ development will be connected with the growing commercialization of
production, introduction of modern livestock technology, the better definition of property
rights, and, in some cases, even the introduction of private land tenure. Som e pastoralists
will benefit from This process will continue to be very painful, and will bring a lot of
resentment. Perhaps, it is possible to somewhat alleviate its negative collateral effects, but
hardly to avoid them completely. However, eventually mobile pastoralism should become
more efficient and more productive along the lines of the capitalist economic efficiency.
A bs tract
Международный центр хазарат-дения
|