On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity

A premium principle is an economic decision rule used by the insurer in order to determine the amount of the net premium for each risk in his portfolio. In this paper we investigate the problem how to determine the premium principle to be used. In Goovaerts & Dhaene (1997), DTEW Research Report...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Datum:2006
Hauptverfasser: Dhaene, J., Kukush, A., Pupashenko, M.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:English
Veröffentlicht: Інститут математики НАН України 2006
Online Zugang:http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4455
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
Назва журналу:Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
Zitieren:On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity / J. Dhaene, A. Kukush, M. Pupashenko // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2006. — Т. 12 (28), № 3-4. — С. 26–42. — Бібліогр.: 4 назв.— англ.

Institution

Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
id irk-123456789-4455
record_format dspace
spelling irk-123456789-44552009-11-12T12:00:20Z On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity Dhaene, J. Kukush, A. Pupashenko, M. A premium principle is an economic decision rule used by the insurer in order to determine the amount of the net premium for each risk in his portfolio. In this paper we investigate the problem how to determine the premium principle to be used. In Goovaerts & Dhaene (1997), DTEW Research Report 9740, K.U.Leuven, we can see some desirable properties of a premium principle. We consider a premium principle for risks of any sign, and prove a representation of premium principle without some property which involves the distribution of a risk. Later we introduce this property as a corollary. 2006 Article On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity / J. Dhaene, A. Kukush, M. Pupashenko // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2006. — Т. 12 (28), № 3-4. — С. 26–42. — Бібліогр.: 4 назв.— англ. 0321-3900 http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4455 en Інститут математики НАН України
institution Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
collection DSpace DC
language English
description A premium principle is an economic decision rule used by the insurer in order to determine the amount of the net premium for each risk in his portfolio. In this paper we investigate the problem how to determine the premium principle to be used. In Goovaerts & Dhaene (1997), DTEW Research Report 9740, K.U.Leuven, we can see some desirable properties of a premium principle. We consider a premium principle for risks of any sign, and prove a representation of premium principle without some property which involves the distribution of a risk. Later we introduce this property as a corollary.
format Article
author Dhaene, J.
Kukush, A.
Pupashenko, M.
spellingShingle Dhaene, J.
Kukush, A.
Pupashenko, M.
On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
author_facet Dhaene, J.
Kukush, A.
Pupashenko, M.
author_sort Dhaene, J.
title On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
title_short On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
title_full On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
title_fullStr On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
title_full_unstemmed On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
title_sort on the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity
publisher Інститут математики НАН України
publishDate 2006
url http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4455
citation_txt On the characterization of premium principle with respect to pointwise comonotonicity / J. Dhaene, A. Kukush, M. Pupashenko // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2006. — Т. 12 (28), № 3-4. — С. 26–42. — Бібліогр.: 4 назв.— англ.
work_keys_str_mv AT dhaenej onthecharacterizationofpremiumprinciplewithrespecttopointwisecomonotonicity
AT kukusha onthecharacterizationofpremiumprinciplewithrespecttopointwisecomonotonicity
AT pupashenkom onthecharacterizationofpremiumprinciplewithrespecttopointwisecomonotonicity
first_indexed 2025-07-02T07:41:46Z
last_indexed 2025-07-02T07:41:46Z
_version_ 1836520158967889920
fulltext Theory of Stochastic Processes Vol. 12 (28), no. 3–4, 2006, pp. 26–42 JAN DHAENE, ALEXANDER KUKUSH, AND MYHAILO PUPASHENKO ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE WITH RESPECT TO POINTWISE COMONOTONICITY1 A premium principle is an economic decision rule used by the insurer in order to determine the amount of the net premium for each risk in his portfolio. In this paper we investigate the problem how to determine the premium principle to be used. In Goovaerts & Dhaene (1997), DTEW Research Report 9740, K.U.Leuven, we can see some desirable properties of a premium principle. We consider a premium principle for risks of any sign, and prove a representation of premium principle without some property which involves the distribution of a risk. Later we introduce this property as a corollary. 1. Introduction Insurance contract can be seen as a risk-exchange between two parties, the insurer and the policyholder. The insurer promises to pay for the financial consequences of the claims produced by the insured risk. In return for this coverage, the policyholder pays a fixed amount, called the premium. Observe that the payments made by the insurer are random, while the payments made by the policyholder are non-random. The pure premium of the insured risk is defined as the expected value of the claim amounts to be paid by the insurer. In practice the insurer will add a risk loading to this pure premium. The sum of the pure premium and the risk loading is called the net premium. Adding acquisition and administration costs to this premium, one gets the gross premium. In this paper we will investigate the problem of determining the net pre- mium. We will assume that the insurer adopts some economic decision rule to determine the amount of the net premium for each risk in his portfolio. Such a principle is called a premium principle, see e.g. Kaas et al. (2001). Several premium principles have been presented in the actuarial literature. Wang (1996) introduced a new class of premium principles which, roughly speaking, compute the net premium as the expectation of the risk under an adjusted measure. In Goovaerts & Dhaene (1997) we can see some desirable properties for a premium principle. They assume that the net premium is not lower than 1Invited lecture. 2000 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 62P05. Key words and phrases. Premium principle, risk, premium, comonotonicity, stochastic dominance. 26 ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 27 the pure premium. We consider premium principle without this property, and than introduce premium principle for risks of any sign. Also we show that Greco’s Representation Theorem, see Dennenberg (1996), do not follow from our statements, and vice versa. 2. Basic definitions for non-negative risks We fix a probability space (Ω, �, P ) . A risk is a non-negative real-valued random variable. Definition 1. Two risks X and Y are 1-comonotonic if the set AXY := {(X (ω) , Y (ω)) : ω ∈ Ω} is comonotonic in R2. Let Γ be a set of risks with such properties: a) X ∈ Γ, d ≥ 0 ⇒ min (X, d) ∈ Γ, (X + d) ∈ Γ, and dX ∈ Γ; b) X ∈ Γ, X (Ω) ⊂ [0, b] , b > 0 ⇒ for Xn := { i 2n b, if i 2n b < X ≤ i+1 2n b, i = 0, 2n − 1 0, if X = 0 ,n = 0, 1, 2, ..., holds: Xn ∈ Γ. c) A ∈ � ⇒ IA ∈ Γ. Hereafter IA = IA (ω) := { 1, if ω ∈ A 0, if ω ∈ Ω\A, and X (Ω) := {X (ω) : ω ∈ Ω} . Definition 2. A premium principle is a functional H : Γ → [0,∞] . For X ∈ Γ, H (X) is called the premium. Remark 1. For risks with the same distribution, the premiums can be different. 3. Properties of a premium principle Property 1 X, Y ∈ Γ, X ≤ Y ⇒ H (X) ≤ H (Y ) . Property 2 If X, Y ∈ Γ, X + Y ∈ Γ, and X, Y are 1-comonotonic, then H (X + Y ) = H (X) + H (Y ) . Property 3 H (1) = 1. Property 4 X ∈ Γ ⇒ lim d→+∞ H [min (X, d)] = H (X) . Remark 2. Properties 1-3 imply that H (aX + b) = aH (X) + b, for all a, b ≥ 0. 4. Layers and distortions Definition 3. Let 0 ≤ a < b. A layer at (a, b) of a risk X is defined by L(a,b) = ⎧⎨ ⎩ 0, if 0 ≤ X ≤ a X − a, if a < X < b b − a, if X ≥ b. 28 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO Definition 4. A function g : � → [0, 1] is called a distortion function if : a) g (∅) = 0, g (Ω) = 1, b) A, B ∈ �, A ⊂ B ⇒ g (A) ≤ g (B) . Lemma 1. Let H be a premium principle satisfying Property 1-3, and g (A) := H (IA) , A ∈ �. Then g is a distortion function. Proof. g (∅) = H (I∅) = H (0) = 0, see Property 2. g (Ω) = H (IΩ) = H (1) = 1, see Property 3. A, B ∈ �, A ⊂ B ⇒ IA ≤ IB ⇒ g(A) ≤ g(B), see Property 1. 5. Characterization of premium principle Let Q (ω) be a certain property of an elementary event ω ∈ Ω, which can be satisfied or not. For a distortion function g we write for brevity g {Q} = g {ω ∈ Ω : Q (ω)} holds. E.g., for a risk X and x > 0 we write g {X > x} = g ({ω ∈ Ω : X (ω) > x}) . Lemma 2. Let H be a premium principle with Properties 1-3. Then there exists a unique distortion function g, such that for all discrete risky X ∈ Γ with only finitely many mass points, we have that (1) H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx. Proof. Let X be discrete risk with finitely many mass points. Then for certain n ≥ 0, X = n∑ 0 xiIAi , where 0 = x0 < x1 < ... < xn, Ai ∈ �, {Ai} form a partition of Ω. Then (we consider the case n ≥ 1 only) L(x0,x1) = (x1 − x0) IA0 , L(x1,x2) = (x2 − x1) IA0∪A1 , . . . L(xn−1,xn) = (xn − xn−1) IA0∪...∪An−1 . We have X = n−1∑ i=0 L(xi,xi+1), ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 29 and the layers L(xi,xi+1), i = 0, n − 1, are pairwise mutually 1-comonotonic risks. Then by Property 2 H (X) = n−1∑ i=0 H ( L(xi,xi+1) ) . But L(xi,xi+1) = (xi+1 − xi) I{X>xi}. Then by Remark 2, H ( L(xi,xi+1) ) = (xi+1 − xi) g {X > xi} , where g (A) := H (IA) , A ∈ �. Then H (X) = n−1∑ i=0 (xi+1 − xi) g {X > xi} = n−1∑ i=0 ∫ xi+1 xi g {X > x} dx = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx, since g (∅) = H (0) = 0 and {X > x} = ∅ for x ≥ xn. By Lemma 1 g is a distortion function. In representation (1) the function g : � → [0, 1] is unique, since for A ∈ � and any g satisfying (1), H (IA) = ∫ ∞ 0 g (A) I[0,1) (x) dx = g (A) . Theorem 1. Assume that the premium principle H satisfies Properties 1-4. Then there exists a unique function g : � → [0, 1] , such that for all risks X ∈ Γ we have that (1a) H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx. Proof. 1◦ Let X ∈ Γ, X (Ω) ⊂ [0, b] , b > 0. For n ≥ 0, we use Xn defined in Section 1. We have by Lemma 2 (2) H (Xn) = ∫ b 0 g {Xn > x} dx, where g is a uniquely defined distortion. Now, Xn ≤ Xn+1 ≤ X, and ∀ω ∈ Ω : Xn (ω) → X (ω) , as n → ∞. Therefore by Property 1, H (Xn) ≤ H (Xn+1) ≤ H (X) . 30 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO Moreover X ≤ Xn + b 2n ⇒ H (X) ≤ H (Xn) + b 2n , we used here Property 1 and Remark 2. Thus (3) lim n→∞ H (Xn) = H (X) . Next, {Xn > x} ↑ {X > x} , then (4) g {Xn > x} ↑ g∗ (x) , g∗ (x) ≤ g {X > x} . We used here part b) of definition 4. Next, the function g∗ (x) := lim n→∞ g {Xn > x} , x ≥ 0, is non-increasing, therefore it has at most countable number of dis- continuous points. Let x be a point of continuity of the function g∗ (x) , x > 0. Then we will show that g∗ (x) = g {X > x} . Indeed, for 0 < ε < x, we have {Xn > x} ⊂ {X > x} ⊂ { Xn > x − b 2n } ⊂ {Xn > x − ε} , for n ≥ nε. Therefore g∗ (x) ≤ g {X > x} ≤ g∗ (x − ε) . But due to our assumption g∗ (x − ε) → g∗ (x) , as ε → 0, therefore g∗ (x) = g {X > x} , and we proved this equality. Now, return to (4). We have lim n→∞ g {Xn > x} = g {X > x} for all x ≥ 0 a.e. with respect to Lebesgue measure. From this fact, (2) and (3) we obtain finally by the dominated convergence theorem: H (X) = ∫ b 0 g {X > x} dx. 2◦ Now let X be an arbitrary risk from Γ. For any d > 0 we have by part 1 of the proof that H [min (X, d)] = ∫ d 0 g {X > x} dx. The desired result follows now from Property 4. ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 31 6. Connection with Wang’s class Introduce stronger property than Property 1. Property 1’ X, Y ∈ Γ, X ≤st Y ⇒ H (X) ≤ H (Y ) . Hereafter X ≤st Y means that X is stochastically dominated by Y. Denote P (�) = {P (A) : A ∈ �} . Corollary 1. Assume that the premium principle H satisfies Properties 1’ and 2 to 4. Then the function g : � → [0, 1] in Theorem 1 has representation (5) g (A) = g0 (P (A)) , A ∈ �, where g0 : P (�) → [0, 1] is non-decreasing, with g0 (0) = 0, g0 (1) = 1. Proof. Property 1’ implies Property 1, therefore the statement of Theorem 1 holds true for the premium principle H , and the function g : � → [0, 1] in (1a) exists and unique. Now let P (A) = P (B) . Then IA ≤st IB and IB ≤st IA. By Property 1’ we have H (IA) = H (IB) ,therefore g (A) = g (B) . Thus representation (5) holds, and the properties of g0 follow from distortion properties of g. Consider stronger property than Property 2. Property 2’ If X, Y ∈ Γ, X + Y ∈ Γ, and X, Y are comonotonic (i.e. ∃Ω0, P (Ω0) = 1 : A0 XY := {(X (ω) , Y (ω)) : ω ∈ Ω0} is comonotonic in R2), then H (X + Y ) = H (X) + H (Y ) . Corollary 2. Assume that the premium principle H satisfies Property 1’ and 2 to 4. Then it satisfies Property 2’ as well, and for all risks X ∈ Γ we have (6) H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g [SX (x)] dx, where SX (x) := P {X > x} , g : P (�) → [0, 1] is non-decreasing, g (0) = 0, g (1) = 1. Moreover the function g in representation (6) is unique. Representation (6) and uniqueness of g follow from Corollary 2. Property 2’ then follows from (6), see Wang (1996). 7. Inverse statement The inverse conclusion of Theorem 1 holds in the next theorem: Theorem 2. The premium principle H : Γ → [0,∞] fulfills the Properties 1-4 if, and only if, there exists a distortion function g : � → [0, 1] , for which: (7) H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx, for any risk X ∈ Γ. Moreover g (A) = H (IA) , A ∈ �. Proof. If H fulfill Properties 1-4 then there exists a distortion function g : � → [0, 1] , for which representation (7) is true, by Theorem 1. 32 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO Now let premium principle H : Γ → [0,∞] is defined by H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx for some distortion function g : � → [0, 1] . Then H fulfills the Properties 1-4. Indeed, the proofs of Properties 1,3 and 4 are straightforward. Now, we prove the key Property 2. Let X, Y be 1-comonotonic risks from Γ. Then these exists a non-negative r.v. Z and two non-decreasing functions f, h : [0,∞) → [0,∞), such that X = f (Z) , Y = h (Z) . We have to prove that (8) ∞∫ 0 g {(f + h) (Z) > x} dx = ∞∫ 0 g {f (Z) > x} dx+ ∞∫ 0 g {h (Z) > x} dx. We do it in several steps. 1◦ It is enough to show (8) for bounded r.v. Z only. Indeed, for d > 0 define Zd = min (d, Z) . Then f (Zd) = min (f (d) , f (Z)) ∈ Γ, and h (Zd) ∈ Γ in a similar way. Suppose that (8) holds for each bounded risk. Then ∞∫ 0 g {(f + h) (Zd) > x} dx = ∞∫ 0 g {f (Zd) > x} dx + ∞∫ 0 g {h (Zd) > x} dx, or (f+h)(d)∫ 0 g {(f + h) (Z) > x} dx = f(d)∫ 0 g {f (Z) > x} dx+ h(d)∫ 0 g {h (Z) > x} dx. Tending d → ∞, we immediately obtain (8). 2◦ Thus we suppose that Z if a bounded non-negative r.v. Assume that f and h are strictly increasing. Then f +h is also strictly increasing. Consider (9) I (f) := ∫ ∞ 0 g {f (Z) > x} dx. Let a = f (0) , b = f (+∞) . Then (10) I (f) = f (0) + ∫ b a g {f (Z) > x} dx. Let 0 ≤ t1 < t2 < . . . be the set of all points of discontinuity of f ( it is a finite or countable set). Denote x− i = f (ti−) , x+ i = f (ti+) , xi = f (ti) . ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 33 If t1 = 0 then x− 1 := x1 = f (0) . We have from (10): (11) I (f) = f (0) + ∑ i≥1 [( xi − x− i ) g {f (Z) ≥ xi} + ( x+ i − xi ) g {f (Z) > xi} ] + ∫ Af g {f (Z) > x} dx, where Af := (a, b) � ∪ i≥1 [ x− i , x+ i ] . Now we define a right-continuous modification of f , frc (t) = { f(t), t ≥ 0, t �= ti, i ≥ 1 f(t+), t = ti,i ≥ 1. Denote Ic(f) = ∫ Af g {f (Z) > x} dx. Then (12) Ic(f) = ∫ Af g {frc (Z) > x} dx = ∫ Af g { Z > f−1 rc (x) } dx. Here f−1 rc is inverse mapping for strictly increasing function frc. Change of variables in Lebesgue integral (12) , t = f−1 rc (x) , leads to the following representation (13) Ic (f) = ∫ [0,∞) {ti,i≥1} g {Z > t} dλfrc (t) , where λfrc is Lebesgue-Stiltjes measure on Borel σ-field ß([0,∞)) ,generated by the function frc. Then I(f) = f(0) + ∑ i≥1 [( xi − x− i ) g {Z ≥ ti} + ( x+ i − xi ) g {Z > ti} ] + ∫ [0,∞) {ti,i≥1} g {Z > t} dλfrc (t) .(14) But Ic (f) = ∫ [0,∞) g {Z > t} dλfrc (t) − ∑ i≥1 g {Z > ti} ( x+ i − x− i ) . We have( xi − x− i ) g {Z ≥ ti} + ( x+ i − xi ) g {Z > ti} − ( x+ i − x− i ) g {Z > ti} = ( xi − x− i ) (g {Z ≥ ti} − g {Z > ti}) . 34 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO Finally I (f) = f (0) + ∑ i≥1 ( xi − x− i ) (g {Z ≥ ti} − g {Z > ti})(15) + ∫ [0,∞) g {Z > t} dλfrc (t) , xi = f (ti) , x− i = f ( t−i ) . Now we are able to show (8) for strictly increasing f and h. Let 0 ≤ u1 < u2 < . . . be the points of discontinuity of f + h. Then by (15) I (f + h) = (f + h) (0) + ∑ i≥1 [ (f + h) (ui) − (f + h) ( u− i )] ×(16) (g {Z ≥ ui} − g {Z > ui}) + ∫ [0,∞) g {Z > t} dλfrc+hrc (t) . But λfrc+hrc = λfrc + λhrc,therefore (16) immediately implies I (f + h) = I (f) + I (h) , since the set of discontinuity of f + h includes both sets of discontinuity of f and h. 3◦ Now, Z is a bounded non-negative r.v., and f, ḣ are non-decreasing. Let fn (t) = f (t) + t n , hn (t) = h (t) + t n , t ∈ [0,∞) , n ≥ 1. Then fn, hn are strictly increasing, and by part 2◦, I (fn + hn) = I (fn) + I (hn) . We show first that lim n→∞ I (fn) = I (f) . Since Z is bounded, all these integrals equal the corresponding intervals on [0, b] , with large enough b. Thus we have to show that (17) lim n→∞ ∫ b 0 g { f (Z) + Z n > x } dx = ∫ b 0 g {f (Z) > x} dx. We have { f (Z) + Z n > x } ↑ {f (Z) > x} . Let g∗ (x) = lim n→∞ g {fn (Z) > x} . The function g∗ is non-increasing. And similarly to part 1◦ of Theorem 1 we have the following: if g∗ is continuous at point x0 then g∗ (x0) = g {f (Z) > x0} . ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 35 But g∗ is continuous a.e. with respect to Lebesgue measure, since it is monotone. Then lim n→∞ g {fn (Z) > x} = g {f (Z) > x} , x ∈ [0.b] , a.e. with respect to Lebesgue measure. Thus (17) holds from the dominated convergence theorem. By part 1◦ relation (8) follows now for any non-negative r.v. Z. Example 1. Let {Pα, α ∈ I} be a family of probability measures on (Ω, �). Let gα : [0, 1] → [0, 1] be non-decreasing function, for which gα (0) = 0, and gα (1) = 1. Introduce two premium principles H1 (X) := ∫ ∞ 0 sup α∈ I gα (Pα {X > x}) dx, H2 (X) := ∫ ∞ 0 inf α∈ I gα (Pα {X > x}) dx; x ∈ Γ. Then due to Theorem 2, both principles fulfill the Properties 1-4. We mention that in general these principles do not have the form (6), i.e. they depend not only on the distribution of X under the basic probability measure P , but on the events {ω : X (ω) > x} , x > 0, as well. Example 2. Another example of this kind could be H3 (X) := ∫ I [∫ ∞ 0 gα (Pα {X > x}) dx ] dμ (α) , where μ is a probability measure on (I, �I) , where �I is a σ-field on I. In this case we have to demand that for any X ∈ Γ the function h (x, α) := gα (Pα {X > x}) , α ∈ I, x > 0, is measurable with respect to the σ-field σ (S × �I), where S is Lebesgue σ-field on (0, +∞) . For both examples, Property 2’ holds as well, if all the probabilities Pα are absolutely continuous w.r.t. P . But Property 1’ need not hold for the examples. 8. Greco’s Representation Theorem Given a family Γ′ of functions X : Ω → R (here R = R ∪ {−∞, +∞}) and a functional H ′ : Γ′ → R, we list the properties of Γ′ and H ′ which play a role in Greco’s Representation Theorem (GRT), stated in Dennenberg (1996). For Γ′ those are a’) X ≥ 0 for all X ∈ Γ′; b’) X ∈ Γ′, d ≥ 0 ⇒ min(X, d) ∈ Γ′, X − min(X, d) ∈ Γ′, and dX ∈ Γ′. For H ′ the following conditions are relevant: (i) X, Y ∈ Γ′, X ≤ Y ⇒ H ′(X) ≤ H ′(Y ); (ii) If X, Y ∈ Γ′, X + Y ∈ Γ′ and X, Y are 1-comonotonic, then H ′ (X + Y ) = H ′ (X) + H ′ (Y ) ; (iii) X ∈ Γ′, X ≥ 0 ⇒ lim d↘0 H ′[X − min(X, d)] = H ′(X) 36 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO (iv) X ∈ Γ′ ⇒ lim b→+∞ H ′[min(X, b)] = H ′(X) Theorem 3(GRT). Given a family Γ′ of functions on Ω with properties a’) and b’) and given a functional H ′ : Γ′ → R with properties (i)-(iv), then there exists a monotone set function γ : 2Ω → R, such that for all X ∈ Γ′ we have that (18) H ′(X) = ∫ ∞ 0 γ{X > x}dx. Remark 3. In GRT H ′(X) ≥ 0, for all risks X ∈ Γ′. This follows from properties (i) and (ii). Now we demonstrate with two examples, that properties of Γ in Definition 1 do not follow from properties of Γ′, listed in GRT, and vice versa. Example 3. Let Ω = {ω}, � = 2Ω and Γ′ consists of one risk X = X(ω) = 0 ∈ Γ′, then Γ′ satisfies properties a’),b’) of GRT. But I{ω} = IΩ = 1 /∈ Γ′, therefore Γ′ does not satisfy properties a)-c), listed in Definition 1. Example 4. Let Ω = {ω1, ω2, ω3}, � = 2Ω. Introduce designation for risk X = (X(ω1), X(ω2), X(ω3)) – well-ordered vector of values of risk X in points ω1, ω2, ω3. First, ∀A ∈ �, IA ∈ Γ therefore (0, 0, 0), (1, 0, 0), (0, 1, 0), (0, 0, 1), (1, 1, 0), (1, 0, 1), (0, 1, 1), (1, 1, 1) ∈ Γ. Then we get all risks X ∈ Γ, so that Γ fulfills properties a) and b), listed in Definition 1. In that way we get risks with one or two different values, because ∀d ≥ 0 all risks: min(X, d), (X + d), dX, Xn (from Definition 1) have less or equal different values then risk X. Later we add to Γ risk X0 with three values, for example X0 = (x1, x2, x3), where 0 < x1 < x2 < x3 < ∞ and those risks, which a necessary by properties a) and b) in Definition 1. It is easy to prove, that for some d : x1 < d < x2, risk X1 = (0, x2 − d, x3 − d) does not belong to Γ(use that we can get risk X1 only from risks with three values, and that for getting X(ω1) = 0 we can use only min(X, 0) or 0 ·X, which do not lead us to risk X1). But by property b’) from GRT we should have, that X1 ∈ Γ′, because X1 = X0 − min(X0, d). Thus Γ fulfills properties from Definition 1 and does not fulfill properties from GRT. 9. Premium of risk of any sign We fix a probability space (Ω, �, P ) , and in this section we call risk to be any real-valued r.v. with finite mean. Thus negative risks are allowed. Definition 1 is still valid. Let Γ be a set of risks with such properties: a1) X ∈ Γ, d ≥ 0 ⇒ (X + d) ∈ Γ, dX ∈ Γ a2) Let d > 0. If X ∈ Γ, X ≥ 0 then min (X, d) ∈ Γ; if X ∈ Γ, X ≤ 0 then max (X,−d) ∈ Γ. b1) Coincides with b) from Section 2. b2) X ∈ Γ, Γ (Ω) ⊂ [−b, 0] , b > 0 ⇒ − (−X)n ∈ Γ,where (−X)n is defined for non-negative r.v. (−X) as in property b) of Γ, see Section 2, where X is replaced to (−X) . ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 37 c1) A ∈ � ⇒ IA, (−IA) ∈ Γ. d1) X ∈ Γ ⇒ X+ ∈ Γ, (−X−) ∈ Γ. Hereafter we use common notations X+ = max (X, 0), X− = −min (X, 0) . Definition 5. A premium principle is a functional H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] . We have to change Property 4. Property 4’. If X ∈ Γ, X ≥ 0 then lim d→+∞ H [min (X, d)] = H (X) , and if X ∈ Γ, X ≤ 0 then lim d→+∞ H [max (X,−d)] = H (X) . Introduce condition on a distortion function: Condition 1. ∀X ∈ Γ : ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g{X > x})dx < ∞. Theorem 4. The premium principle H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] fulfills the Prop- erties 1 to 3, and 4’ if, and only if, there exists a distortion functions g : � → [0, 1] which satisfies Condition 1 and for all risks X ∈ Γ, (19) H (X) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {X > x}) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx. Moreover g (A) = H (IA) , A ∈ �. Proof. 1◦ Let H fulfills the Properties 1 to 3, and 4’. We prove the represen- tation (19). Let X ∈ Γ. Then X = X+ + (−X−), and both X+ and (−X−) belong to Γ. Moreover X+ = f1 (X) ,−X− = f2 (X) , with non-decreasing functions f1 and f2. Therefore X+, (−X−) are 1-comonotonic. Then by Property 2 H (X) = H (X+) + H(−X−). Now, X+ ∈ Γ+ := {Y+ : Y ∈ Γ} . The set of risks Γ+ satisfies prop- erties a) and c) from Section 2, due to the properties of Γ listed in this section. And H restricted to Γ+ satisfies Properties 1 to 4. Therefore by Theorem 2 there exists a distortion g : � → [0, 1] , such that H (X+) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X+ > x} dx, But ∀x > 0 : {X+ > x} = {X > x} , therefore H (X+) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx. Moreover g (A) = H (IA) , A ∈ �. 38 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO 2◦ Next, consider the class of risks Γ− := {Y− : Y ∈ Γ} . Define H1 (Y−) := −H (−Y−) , Y− ∈ Γ−. The class Γ− satisfies properties a) to c) from Section 2. A premium principle H1 : Γ− → [0, +∞) satisfies the following properties. -Property 1 follows from Property 1 of H. Indeed, X− ≤ Y− ⇒ H (−X−) ≥ H (−Y−) ⇒ H1 (X−) ≤ H1 (Y−) . -Properties 2 and 3 follow from Properties 2 and 3 of H. -Property 4 follows from the second part of Property 4’ for H. Then by the statement similar to Theorem 2 there exists a distor- tion h, such that H1 (U) = ∫ ∞ 0 h {U > x} dx = ∫ ∞ 0 h {U ≥ x} dx, since h {U ≥ x} = h {U > x} a.e. with respect to Lebesgue measure, see the proof of Theorem 1. Moreover h (A) = H1 (IA) , A ∈ �. Then define g1 (A) = 1 − h ( A ) , A ∈ �. It is a distortion as well, and g1 (A) = 1 − H1 (IA) = 1 + H (−IA) = H (1 − IA) = H (IA) = g (A) . Therefore g1 = g, and H1 (U) = ∫ ∞ 0 (1 − g {U < x}) dx = ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {−U > x}) dx. Finally, for X ∈ Γ, H (X) = H (−X−) + H (X+) = −H1 (X−) + H (X+) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {−X− > x}) dx + H (X+) , H (X) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {X > x}) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx, since for x < 0, {X > x} = {−X− > x} . 3◦ Now, let H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] has representation (19), with a distor- tion function g : � → [0, 1], satisfying Condition 1. Then equality H (IA) = g (A) , A ∈ �, follows immediately, and the properties 1, 3 and 4’ are easily verified. ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 39 Prove the Property 2 for H. The right hand side of (19) is defined for all risks, there fore we can assume now that H is defined by (19) for all risks, not only for the risks for Γ. Let X, Y be two 1-comonotonic risks. First consider the case X ≥ −d, Y ≥ −d, with fixed positive d. Then since (19) implies H (Y + c) = H (Y ) + c, c ∈ R, for any risk Y , we have H (X + Y ) = H ((X + d) + (Y + d)) − 2d. But X + d and Y + d are non-negative 1-comonotomic risks. For any non-negative risk Y, H (Y ) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {Y > x} dx =: G (Y ) . But the functional G fulfills Property 2 for non-negative risks, due to Theorem 2. Then H (X + Y ) = H (X + d) + H (Y + d) − 2d = H (X) + d + H (Y ) + d − 2d = H (X) + H (Y ) , and we showed Property 2 for bounded from below risks. Let now X, Y be arbitrary 1-comonotonic risks. Then X = f (Z), Y = h (Z) , where Z is a r.v., and f, h are non-decreasing. We fix c ∈ R and for any r.v.U define Uc = max (U, c) . Now, f (Zc) and h (Zc) are bounded from below 1-comonotonic risks, then H (f (Zc) + h (Zc)) = H (f (Zc)) + H (h (Zc)) , (20) H ((f + h) (Zc)) = H (f (Zc)) + H (h (Zc)) . Let α (Z) be a risk, with non-decreasing function α : R → R. Then α (Zα) = (α (Z))b , with b := α (c) . And due to the integral repre- sentation (19), lim c→−∞ H (α (Zc)) = H (α (Z)) . Now, in (20) we tend c → −∞ and obtain H ((f + h) (Z)) = H (f (Z)) + H (h (Z)) . Now, instead of Property 1 we consider stronger Property 1’. Introduce condition on function g0 : P (�) → [0, 1] much as Condition 1 on distortion function. Condition 2. ∀X ∈ Γ : ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g0(SX(x)))dx < ∞. Corollary 3. The premium principle H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] fulfills the Properties 1’, 2, 3 and 4’ if, and only if, these exists a function g0 : P (�) → [0, 1] , 40 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO which satisfies Condition 2, g0 (0) = 0, g0 (1) = 1, g0 is non-decreasing, and such that for any risk X ∈ Γ, (21) H (X) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g0 (SX (x))) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g0 (SX (x)) dx, where SX (x) := P {X > x} , x ∈ R. Moreover g0 (q) = H (Bq) , q ∈ P (�) , where Bq is Bernoulli r.v. with parameter q. Proof. Let H satisfies the properties listed above. Then weaker Property 1 holds as well, and representation (19) holds, with g (A) = H (IA) . But IA d = Bq, with q := P (A) . Thus g (A) depends only on q = P (A) , g (A) = g0 (P (A)) , and (21) follows. The desired properties of g0 follow from corresponding properties of g. Next, let representation (21) holds for the principle H . Then (19) holds, with g (A) := g0 (P (A)) , A ∈ �. The distortion properties of g follow from the properties of g0. Then by Theorem 4, H fulfills Properties 1 to 3, and 4’. The Property 1’ follows now from Property 1, since H (X) in (21) is determined by the distribution of X. Remark 4. For the premium principle (19), defined for all risks X, we show the property: (22) H (X − d) = H (X) − d, d > 0, which was used in part 3◦ of the proof of Theorem 4. We have H (X − d) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {X > x + d}) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x + d} dx = − ∫ d −∞ (1 − g {X > t}) dt + ∫ ∞ d g {X > t} dt = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {X > t}) dt + ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > t} dt − ∫ d 0 (1 − g {X > t}) − ∫ d 0 g {X > t} dt = H (X) − d. Thus (22) is proven. 10. Corollary Introduce an important property of a premium principle: Property 5 X ∈ Γ ⇒ H(X) ≥ EX. This property means that the net premium is not lower than the pure pre- mium. ON THE CHARACTERIZATION OF PREMIUM PRINCIPLE 41 Lemma 3. Let H be a premium principle satisfying Property 1-3,5, and g(A) := H(IA), A ∈ �. Then g is a distortion function, moreover g(A) ≥ P (A), for all A ∈ �. Proof. Distortion properties of g follow from Lemma 1. Let A ∈ �, then g(A) = H(IA) ≥ EIA = P (A). Now we have the next corollary of Theorem 2. Theorem 5. The premium principle H : Γ → [0,∞] fulfills the Properties 1-5 if, and only if, there exists a distortion function g : � → [0, 1] , which satisfies: (1) H (X) = ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx, for any risk X ∈ Γ, (2) g (A) ≥ P (A) , for any A ∈ �. Moreover g (A) = H (IA) , A ∈ �. Now return to Examples 1,2. Introduce property of {Pα, α ∈ I} : Pα (A) ≥ CαP (A) , for all α ∈ Γ, A ∈ �. Here 0 < Cα ≤ 1. We mention that if Cα0 = 1 then Pα0 = P. Let gα : [0, 1] → [0, 1] be non-decreasing function, for which gα (0) = 0, gα (1) = 1, and gα (q) ≥ min (1, q/Cα) for all q ∈ [0, 1] . Then due to Theorem 5, prin- ciples H1, H2, H3 fulfill the Properties 1-5. Now we have the following corollary of Theorem 4. Theorem 6. The premium principle H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] fulfills the Prop- erties 1, 2, 3’, 4’, and 5 if, and only if, there exists a distortion functions g : � → [0, 1] which satisfies: (23) a) H (X) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g {X > x}) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g {X > x} dx, for any risk X ∈ Γ, (24) b) g (A) ≥ P (A) , for any A ∈ �. Moreover g (A) = H (IA) , A ∈ �. Finally we modify Corollary 3. Corollary 4. The premium principle H : Γ → (−∞, +∞] fulfills the Properties 1’, 2, 3’, 4’, and 5 if, and only if, these exists a function g0 : P (�) → [0, 1] , g0 (0) = 0, g0 (1) = 1, g0 is non-decreasing, g0 (q) ≥ q, q ∈ P (�) , such that for any risk X ∈ Γ, (25) H (X) = − ∫ 0 −∞ (1 − g0 (SX (x))) dx + ∫ ∞ 0 g0 (SX (x)) dx, 42 J. DHAENE, A. KUKUSH, AND M. PUPASHENKO where SX (x) := P {X > x} , x ∈ R. Moreover g0 (q) = H (Bq) , q ∈ P (�) , where Bq is Bernoulli r.v. with parameter q. References 1. Wang, S.S., Premium calculations by transforming the layer premium density. ASTIN Bulletin, 26, (1996), 71–92. 2. Goovaerts, M.J. and Dhaene, J., On the characterization of Wang’s class of premium principle. DTEW Research Report 9740, K.U.Leuven, (1997). 3. Denneberg, D., Non-Additive Measure and Integral. Kluwer Academic Publish- ers, Boston, (1996). 4. Kaas, R., Goovaerts, M.J., Dhaene, J. and Denuit, M., Modern Acturial Risk Theory. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, (2001). Department of Applied Economics, K.U.Leuven, Naamsestraat 69, B-3000 Leuven, Belgium E-mail address: jan.dhaene@econ.kuleuven.be Department of Probability Theory and Mathematical Statistics, Kyiv National Taras Shevchenko University, Vladimirskaya st.64, 01033 Kyiv, Ukraine E-mail address: alexander kukush@univ.kiev.ua Department of Mechanics and Mathematics, Kyiv National Taras Shev- chenko University, Vladimirskaya st.64, 01033 Kyiv, Ukraine E-mail address: myhailo.pupashenko@gmail.com