Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market.
Saved in:
Date: | 2007 |
---|---|
Main Authors: | , |
Format: | Article |
Language: | English |
Published: |
Інститут математики НАН України
2007
|
Online Access: | http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472 |
Tags: |
Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
|
Journal Title: | Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine |
Cite this: | Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ. |
Institution
Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraineid |
irk-123456789-4472 |
---|---|
record_format |
dspace |
spelling |
irk-123456789-44722009-11-20T12:00:24Z Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market. 2007 Article Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ. 0321-3900 http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472 en Інститут математики НАН України |
institution |
Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine |
collection |
DSpace DC |
language |
English |
description |
We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process
consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors
on optimal investment in this market. |
format |
Article |
author |
Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. |
spellingShingle |
Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
author_facet |
Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. |
author_sort |
Inoue, A. |
title |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
title_short |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
title_full |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
title_fullStr |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
title_full_unstemmed |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
title_sort |
remark on optimal investment in a market with memory |
publisher |
Інститут математики НАН України |
publishDate |
2007 |
url |
http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472 |
citation_txt |
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ. |
work_keys_str_mv |
AT inouea remarkonoptimalinvestmentinamarketwithmemory AT nakanoy remarkonoptimalinvestmentinamarketwithmemory |
first_indexed |
2025-07-02T07:42:34Z |
last_indexed |
2025-07-02T07:42:34Z |
_version_ |
1836520208895836160 |
fulltext |
Theory of Stochastic Processes
Vol.13 (29), no.1-2, 2007, pp.66-76
AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
REMARK ON OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A
MARKET WITH MEMORY
We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semi-
martingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process
consists of n independent components and each component has mem-
ory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors
on optimal investment in this market.
1. Introduction
In this paper, we extend results of Inoue and Nakano [12] on optimal
investment in a financial market model with memory. This market model
M consists of n risky and one riskless assets. The price of the riskless
asset is denoted by S0(t) and that of the ith risky asset by Si(t). We put
S(t) = (S1(t), . . . , Sn(t))
′, where A′ denotes the transpose of a matrix A.
The dynamics of the Rn-valued process S(t) are described by the stochastic
differential equation
dSi(t) = Si(t)
[
μi(t)dt +
∑n
j=1 σij(t)dYj(t)
]
, t ≥ 0, Si(0) = si,
i = 1, . . . , n,
(1)
while those of S0(t) by the ordinary differential equation
dS0(t) = r(t)S0(t)dt, t ≥ 0, S0(0) = 1,
where the coefficients r(t) ≥ 0, μi(t), and σij(t) are continuous deterministic
functions on [0,∞) and the initial prices si are positive constants. We
assume that the n× n volatility matrix σ(t) = (σij(t))1≤i,j≤n is nonsingular
for t ≥ 0.
Invited lecture.
2000 Mathematics Subject Classifications. Primary 91B28, 60G10; Secondary 62P05,
93E20.
Key words and phrases. Optimal investment, long term investment, processes with
memory, processes with stationary increments, Riccati equations.
66
OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 67
We define the jth component Yj(t) of the Rn-valued driving noise process
Y (t) = (Y1(t), . . . , Yn(t))
′ of (1) by the autoregressive type equation
dYj(t)
dt
= −
∫ t
−∞
pje
−qj(t−s) dYj(s)
ds
ds +
dWj(t)
dt
, t ∈ R, Yj(0) = 0,
where W (t) = (W1(t), . . . , Wn(t))′, t ∈ R, is an Rn-valued standard Brown-
ian motion defined on a complete probability space (Ω,F , P ), the derivatives
dYj(t)/dt and dWj(t)/dt are in the random distribution sense, and pj ’s and
qj ’s are constants such that
0 < qj < ∞, −qj < pj < ∞, j = 1, . . . , n (2)
(see Anh–Inoue [1]). Equivalently, we may define Yj(t) by the moving-
average type representation
Yj(t) = Wj(t) −
∫ t
0
[∫ s
−∞
pje
−(qj+pj)(s−u)dWj(u)
]
ds, t ∈ R
(see [1], Examples 2.12 and 2.14). The components Yj(t), j = 1, . . . , n,
are Gaussian processes with stationary increments that are independent
of each other. Each Yj(t) has short memory that is described by the two
parameters pj and qj . Notice that, in the special case pj = 0, Yj(t) reduces
to the Brownian motion Wj(t).
The underlying information structure of the market model M is the
filtration (Ft)t≥0 defined by
Ft := σ (σ(Y (s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t) ∪N ) , t ≥ 0,
where N is the P -null subsets of F . With respect to this filtration, Y (t) is a
semimartingale. In fact, we have the following two kinds of semimartingale
representations of Y (t) (see Anh et al. [2], Example 5.3, and Inoue et al.
[13], Theorem 2.1):
Yj(t) = Bj(t) −
∫ t
0
[∫ s
0
kj(s, u)dYj(u)
]
ds, t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (3)
Yj(t) = Bj(t) −
∫ t
0
[∫ s
0
lj(s, u)dBj(u)
]
ds, t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (4)
where, for j = 1, . . . , n, (Bj(t))t≥0 is the innovation process, i.e., an R-
valued standard Brownian motion such that
σ(Yj(s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t) = σ(Bj(s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t), t ≥ 0,
and Bj’s are independent of each other. The point of (3) and (4) is that
the deterministic kernels kj(t, s) and lj(t, s) are given explicitly by
kj(t, s) = pj(2qj + pj)
(2qj + pj)e
qjs − pje
−qjs
(2qj + pj)2eqjt − p2
je
−qjt
, 0 ≤ s ≤ t, (5)
lj(t, s) = e−(pj+qj)(t−s)lj(s), 0 ≤ s ≤ t, (6)
68 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
with
lj(s) := pj
[
1 − 2pjqj
(2qj + pj)2e2qjs − p2
j
]
, s ≥ 0. (7)
There already exist many references in which the standard driving noise,
that is, Brownian motion, is replaced by a different one, such as fractional
Brownian motion, so that the market model can capture memory effect. See,
e.g., Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [3], Hu et al. [11], Mishura [15] and
Heyde and Leonenko [10]. Among such models, the above model M driven
by Y (t) which is a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments is
possibly the simplest one. One advantage of M is that, assuming σij(t) =
σij , real constants, we can easily estimate the characteristic parameters pj,
qj and σij from stock price data. See [12], Appendix C, for this parameter
estimation from real market data.
In the market M, an agent with initial endowment x ∈ (0,∞) invests,
at each time t, πi(t)X
x,π(t) dollars in the ith risky asset for i = 1, . . . , n and
[1 − ∑n
i=1 πi(t)]X
x,π(t) dollars in the riskless asset, where Xx,π(t) denotes
the agent’s wealth at time t. The wealth process Xx,π(t) is governed by the
stochastic differential equation
dXx,π(t)
Xx,π(t)
=
[
1 −
∑n
i=1
πi(t)
] dS0(t)
S0(t)
+
∑n
i=1
πi(t)
dSi(t)
Si(t)
, Xx,π(0) = x.
Here, the self-financing strategy π(t) = (π1(t), . . . , πn(t))′ is chosen from the
admissible class
AT :=
{
π = (π(t))0≤t≤T :
π is an Rn-valued, progressively measurable
process satisfying
∫ T
0
‖π(t)‖2dt < ∞ a.s.
}
for the finite time horizon of length T ∈ (0,∞), where ‖ · ‖ denotes the
Euclidean norm of Rn. If the time horizon is infinite, π(t) is chosen from
A := {(π(t))t≥0 : (π(t))0≤t≤T ∈ AT for every T ∈ (0,∞)} .
Let α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and c ∈ R. In [12], the following three optimal
investment problems for the model M are considered:
V (T, α) := sup
π∈AT
1
α
E [(Xx,π(T ))α] , (8)
J(α) := sup
π∈A
lim sup
T→∞
1
αT
log E [(Xx,π(T ))α] , (9)
I(c) := sup
π∈A
lim sup
T→∞
1
T
log P
[
Xx,π(T ) ≥ ecT
]
. (10)
Problem (8) is the classical optimal investment problem that dates back to
Merton (cf. Karatzas and Shreve [14]). Hu et al. [11] studied this problem for
OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 69
a Black–Scholes type model driven by fractional Brownian motion. Problem
(9) is a kind of long term optimal investment problem which is studied by
Bielecki and Pliska [4], and also by other authors under various settings,
including Fleming and Sheu [5,6], Nagai and Peng [16], Pham [17,18], Hata
and Iida [7], and Hata and Sekine [8,9]. Problem (10) is another type of
long term optimal investment problem, the aim of which is to maximize the
large deviation probability that the wealth grows at a higher rate than the
given benchmark c. Pham [17,18] studied this problem and established a
duality relation between Problems (9) and (10). Subsequently, this problem
is studied by Hata and Iida [7] and Hata and Sekine [8,9] under different
settings.
In [12], Problems (8)–(10) are studied for the market model M which
has memory. There, the following condition, rather than (2), is assumed in
solving (8)–(10):
0 < qj < ∞, 0 ≤ pj < ∞, j = 1, . . . , n. (11)
Thus, in [12], pj ≥ 0 rather than pj > −qj for j = 1, . . . , n. In this paper,
we focus on Problems (8) and (9), and extends the results of [12] so that
pj ’s may take negative values. The key to this extension is to show the
existence of solution for a relevant Riccati type equation.
In Sections 2 and 3, we review the results of [12] on Problems (8) and
(9), respectively, and, in Section 4, we extend these results.
2. Optimal investment over a finite horizon
In this section, we review the result of [12] on the finite horizon optimiza-
tion problem (8) for the market model M. We assume α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0}
and (11).
Let Y (t) = (Y1(t), . . . , Yn(t))
′ and B(t) = (B1(t), . . . , Bn(t))′ be the driv-
ing noise and innovation processes, respectively, described in the previous
section. We define an Rn-valued deterministic function λ(t) = (λ1(t), . . . ,
λn(t))′ by
λ(t) := σ−1(t) [μ(t) − r(t)1] , t ≥ 0, (12)
where 1 := (1, . . . , 1)′ ∈ Rn. For kj(t, s)’s in (5), we put
k(t, s) := diag(k1(t, s), . . . , kn(t, s)), 0 ≤ s ≤ t.
Let ξ(t) = (ξ1(t), . . . , ξn(t))
′ be the Rn-valued process
∫ t
0
k(t, s)dY (s), i.e.,
ξj(t) :=
∫ t
0
kj(t, s)dYj(s), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n. (13)
Let β be the conjugate exponent of α, i.e.,
(1/α) + (1/β) = 1.
70 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
Notice that 0 < β < 1 (resp. −∞ < β < 0) if −∞ < α < 0 (resp.
0 < α < 1).
We put l(t) := diag(l1(t), . . . , ln(t)), p := diag(p1, . . . , pn), and q :=
diag(q1, . . . , qn) with lj(t)’s as in (7). We also put
ρ(t) = (ρ1(t), . . . , ρn(t))′, b(t) = diag(b1(t), . . . , bn(t))
with
ρj(t) := −βlj(t)λj(t), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (14)
bj(t) := −(pj + qj) + βlj(t), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n. (15)
We consider the following one-dimensional backward Riccati equations: for
j = 1, . . . , n
Ṙj(t) − l2j (t)R
2
j (t) + 2bj(t)Rj(t) + β(1 − β) = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T,
Rj(T ) = 0.
(16)
We have the following result on the existence of solution to (16).
Lemma 1 ([12], Lemma 2.1). Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}.
1. If pj = 0, then (16) has a unique solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ).
2. If pj > 0 and −∞ < α < 0, then (16) has a unique nonnegative
solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ).
3. If pj > 0 and 0 < α < 1, then (16) has a unique solution Rj(t) ≡
Rj(t; T ) such that Rj(t) ≥ bj(t)/l
2
j (t) for t ∈ [0, T ].
In what follows, we write Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) for the unique solution to
(16) in the sense of Lemma 1, and we put R(t) := diag(R1(t), . . . , Rn(t)).
For j = 1, . . . , n, let vj(t) ≡ vj(t; T ) be the solution to the following
one-dimensional linear equation:
v̇j(t) + [bj(t) − l2j (t)Rj(t; T )]vj(t) + β(1 − β)λj(t) − Rj(t; T )ρj(t) = 0,
0 ≤ t ≤ T, vj(T ) = 0.
(17)
We put v(t) ≡ v(t; T ) := (v1(t; T ), . . . , vn(t; T ))′.
For j = 1, . . . , n and (t, T ) ∈ Δ, write
gj(t; T ) := v2
j (t; T )l2j (t) + 2ρj(t)vj(t; T ) − l2j (t)Rj(t; T ) − β(1 − β)λ2
j(t),
where
Δ := {(t, T ) : 0 < T < ∞, 0 ≤ t ≤ T}.
Recall that we have assumed α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and (11). Here is the
solution to Problem (8) under the condition (11).
OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 71
Theorem 2 ([12], Theorem 2.3). For T ∈ (0,∞), the strategy (π̂T (t))0≤t≤T
∈ AT defined by
π̂T (t) := (σ′)−1(t) [(1 − β)λ(t) − {1 − β + l(t)R(t;T )}ξ(t) + l(t)v(t;T )] (18)
is the unique optimal strategy for Problem (8). The value function V (T ) ≡
V (T, α) in (8) is given by
V (T ) =
1
α
[xS0(T )]α exp
[
(1 − α)
2
∑n
j=1
∫ T
0
gj(t; T )dt
]
.
3. Optimal investment over an infinite horizon
In this section, we review the result of [12] on the infinite horizon opti-
mization problem (9) for the financial market model M. Throughout this
section, we assume (11) and the following two conditions:
lim
T→∞
1
T
∫ T
0
r(t)dt = r̄ with r̄ ∈ R, (19)
lim
T→∞
λ(t) = λ̄ with λ̄ = (λ̄1, . . . , λ̄n)′ ∈ Rn. (20)
Here recall λ(t) = (λ1(t), . . . , λn(t))′ from (12).
Let α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and β be its conjugate exponent. Let j ∈
{1, . . . , n}. For bj(t) in (15), we have limt→∞ bj(t) = b̄j , where
b̄j := −(1 − β)pj − qj .
Notice that b̄j < 0. We consider the equation
p2
jx
2 − 2b̄jx − β(1 − β) = 0. (21)
When pj = 0, we write R̄j for the unique solution β(1 − β)/(2qj) of this
linear equation. If pj > 0, then
b̄2
j + β(1 − β)p2
j = (1 − β)[(pj + qj)
2 − q2
j ] + q2
j ≥ q2
j > 0,
so that we may write R̄j for the larger solution to the quadratic equation
(21). Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. For ρj(t) in (14), we have limt→∞ ρj(t) = ρ̄j, where
ρ̄j := −βpjλ̄j.
Define v̄j by (
b̄j − p2
j R̄j
)
v̄j + β(1 − β)λ̄j − R̄j ρ̄j = 0.
72 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
For j = 1, . . . , n and −∞ < α < 1, α = 0, we put
Fj(α) :=
(pj + qj)
2λ̄2
jα
[(1 − α)(pj + qj)2 + αpj(pj + 2qj)]
,
and
Gj(α) := (pj + qj) − qjα
−(1 − α)1/2 [(1 − α)(pj + qj)
2 + αpj(pj + 2qj)]
1/2
.
Recall ξ(t) from (13). Taking into account (18), we consider π̂ =
(π̂(t))t≥0 ∈ A defined by
π̂(t) := (σ′)−1(t)
[
(1 − β)λ(t) − (1 − β + pR̄)ξ(t) + pv̄
]
, t ≥ 0,
where R̄ := diag(R̄1, . . . , R̄n), v̄ := (v̄1, . . . , v̄n)′, and p := diag(p1, . . . , pn).
We define
α∗ := max(α1∗, . . . , αn∗) (22)
with
αj∗ :=
{
−∞ if −∞ < pj ≤ 2qj,
−3 − 8qj
pj−2qj
if 2qj < pj < ∞.
(23)
Notice that α∗ ∈ [−∞,−3).
Recall that we have assumed (11), (19) and (20). Here is the solution
to Problem (9) under the condition (11).
Theorem 3 ([12], Theorem 3.4). Let α∗ < α < 1, α = 0. Then π̂ is an
optimal strategy for Problem (9) with limit rather than limsup in (9). The
optimal growth rate J(α) in (9) is given by
J(α) = r̄ +
1
2α
n∑
j=1
Fj(α) +
1
2α
n∑
j=1
Gj(α).
4. Extensions
In this section, we extend Theorems 2 and 3 so that pj’s may take
negative values. The key is to extend Lemma 1 properly. We assume
α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and (2).
We put, for j = 1, . . . , n,
a1j(t) = lj(t)
2,
a2j(t) = βlj(t) − (pj + qj),
a3 = β(1 − β).
OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 73
Then the Riccati equation (16) becomes
Ṙj(t) − a1j(t)R
2
j (t) + 2a2j(t)Rj(t) + a3 = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T,
Rj(T ) = 0.
Note that lj(t) is increasing and satisfies
lj(0) =
pj(pj + 2qj)
2(pj + qj)
≤ lj(t) ≤ pj , t ≥ 0.
Proposition 4. Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and
0 < α ≤
(
pj + qj
pj + qj − lj(0)
)2
. (24)
1. It holds that a2j(t) ≤ 0 for t ≥ 0.
2. It holds that a2j(t)
2 + a1j(t)a3 ≥ 0 for t ≥ 0.
Proof. We have
a2j(t) = βlj(t) − (pj + qj) ≤ βlj(0) − (pj + qj),
whence a2j(t) ≤ 0 if β ≥ (pj + qj)/lj(0) or
α ≤ (pj + qj)/lj(0)
[(pj + qj)/lj(0)] − 1
=
pj + qj
pj + qj − lj(0)
.
However, 0 < (pj + qj)/[pj + qj − lj(0)] < 1, whence
pj + qj
pj + qj − lj(0)
>
(
pj + qj
pj + qj − lj(0)
)2
.
Thus the first assertion follows.
We have
a2j(t)
2 + a1j(t)a3 = βlj(t)
2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(t)β + (pj + qj)
2
≥ βlj(0)2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(0)β + (pj + qj)
2
= β[{(pj + qj) − lj(0)}2 − (pj + qj)
2] + (pj + qj)
2,
whence a2j(t)
2 + a1j(t)a3 ≥ 0 if
β ≥ (pj + qj)
2
(pj + qj)2 − [(pj + qj) − lj(0)]2
.
However, this is equivalent to α ≤ [(pj + qj)/{pj + qj − lj(0)}]2. Thus the
second assertion follows.
Lemma 5. Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}.
74 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
1. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and −∞ < α < 0. Then (16) has a unique
nonnegative solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ).
2. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and (24). Then (16) has a unique solution
Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) such that Rj(t) ≥ R∗
j (t) for t ∈ [0, T ], where
R∗
j (t) :=
a2j(t) +
√
a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3
a1j(t)
.
Proof. The first assertion follows in the same way as in the proof of [12],
Lemma 2.1 (ii). Thus we prove the second assertion.
Notice that R∗
j (t) is the larger solution to the quadratic equation
a1j(t)x
2 − 2a2j(t)x − a3 = 0. Thus
a1j(t)R
∗
j (t)
2 − 2a2j(t)R
∗
j (t) − a3 = 0. (25)
Since a1j(t) > 0, a2j(t) ≤ 0 and a3 < 0, we see that R∗
j (t) ≤ 0. The equation
for V (t) := Rj(t) − R∗
j (t) becomes
V̇ (t) − a1j(t)V (t)2 + 2[a2j(t) − a1j(t)R
∗
j (t)]V (t) + Ṙ∗
j (t) = 0. (26)
By differenciating (25), we get
ȧ1j(t)R
∗
j (t)
2 + 2a1j(t)R
∗
j (t)Ṙ
∗
j (t) − 2ȧ2jR
∗
j (t) − 2a2j(t)Ṙ
∗
j (t) = 0,
whence
Ṙ∗
j (t) =
2ȧ2j(t)R
∗
j (t) − ȧ1j(t)R
∗(t)2
2
√
a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3
.
Now
2ȧ2j(t)R
∗
j (t) − ȧ1jR
∗
j (t)
2 = −2l̇j(t)R
∗
j (t){lj(t)R∗
j (t) − β}.
Since
a2j(t)
2 + a1j(t)a3 = βlj(t)
2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(t)β + (pj + qj)
2 < (pj + qj)
2,
we see that
lj(t)R
∗
j (t) − β =
1
lj(t)
[
−(pj + qj) +
√
a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3
]
> 0.
Thus Ṙ∗
j (t) ≥ 0. This and a1j(t) > 0 imply that (26) has a unique nonneg-
ative solution. The second assertion follows from this.
We define
α∗ := min(α∗
1, . . . , α
∗
n)
OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 75
with
α∗
j :=
{ (
pj+qj
pj+qj−lj(0)
)2
if − qj < pj < 0,
1 if 0 ≤ pj < ∞.
Notice that α∗ ∈ (0, 1]. Recall α∗ from (22).
Taking the solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) of (16) in the sense of Lemma 1 or
5 and running through the same arguments as those in [12], Sections 2 and
3, we obtain the following extensions to Theorems 2 and 3.
Theorem 6. We assume (2) and −∞ < α < α∗, α = 0. Then the same
conclusions as those of Theorem 2 hold.
Theorem 7. We assume (2), (19), (20) and α∗ < α < α∗, α = 0. Then
the same conclusions as those of Theorem 3 hold.
Bibliography
1. Anh, V. and Inoue, A., Financial markets with memory I: Dynamic models,
Stoch. Anal. Appl., 23, (2005), 275–300.
2. Anh, V., Inoue, A. and Kasahara, Y., Financial markets with memory II:
Innovation processes and expected utility maximization, Stoch. Anal. Appl.,
23, (2005), 301–328.
3. Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N., Non-Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlen-
beck-based models and some of their uses in financial economics, J. Roy.
Statist. Soc. Ser. B, 63, (2001), 167–241.
4. Bielecki, T. R. and Pliska, S. R., Risk sensitive dynamic asset management,
Appl. Math. Optim., 39, (1999), 337–360.
5. Fleming W. H. and Sheu, S. J., Risk-sensitive control and an optimal in-
vestment model, Math. Finance, 10, (2000), 197–213.
6. Fleming, W. H. and Sheu, S. J., Risk-sensitive control and an optimal
investment model (II), Ann. Appl. Probab., 12, (2000), 730–767.
7. Hata, H. and Iida, Y., A risk-sensitive stochastic control approach to an
optimal investment problem with partial information, Finance Stoch., 10,
(2006), 395–426.
8. Hata, H. and Sekine, J., Solving long term optimal investment problems
with Cox-Ingersoll-Ross interest rates, Adv. Math. Econ., 8, (2006), 231–
255.
9. Hata, H. and Sekine, J., Solving a large deviations control problem with a
nonlinear factor model, preprint.
10. Heyde, C. C. and Leonenko, N. N., Student processes, Adv. in Appl.
Probab., 37, (2005), 342–365.
11. Hu, Y. Øksendal, B. and Sulem, A., Optimal consumption and portfolio
in a Black-Scholes market driven by fractional Brownian motion, Infin.
Dimens. Anal. Quantum Probab. Relat. Top., 6, (2003), 519–536.
76 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO
12. Inoue, A. and Nakano, Y., Optimal long term investment model with mem-
ory, Appl. Math. Optim., to appear.
Available at http://arxiv.org/abs/math.PR/0506621.
13. Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. and Anh, V., Linear filtering of systems with memory
and application to finance, J. Appl. Math. Stoch. Anal., 2006, (2006), 1–26.
14. Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S. E., Methods of mathematical finance, Springer-
Verlag, New York, (1998).
15. Mishura, Yu., Fractional stochastic integration and Black–Scholes equa-
tion for fractional Brownian motion model with stochastic volatility, Stoch.
Stoch. Rep., 76, (2004), 363–381.
16. Nagai, H. and Peng, S., Risk-sensitive dynamic portfolio optimization with
partial information on infinite time horizon, Ann. Appl. Probab., 12, (2002),
173–195.
17. Pham, H., A large deviations approach to optimal long term investment,
Finance Stoch., 7, (2003), 169–195.
18. Pham, H., A risk-sensitive control dual approach to a large deviations con-
trol problem, Systems Control Lett., 49, (2003), 295–309.
Department of Mathematics, Faculty of Science, Hokkaido Univer-
sity, Sapporo 060-0810, Japan.
E-mail address: inoue@math.sci.hokudai.ac.jp
Center for the Study of Finance and Insurance, Osaka University,
Toyonaka 560-8531, Japan.
E-mail address: y-nakano@sigmath.es.osaka-u.ac.jp
|