Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory

We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market.

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Date:2007
Main Authors: Inoue, A., Nakano, Y.
Format: Article
Language:English
Published: Інститут математики НАН України 2007
Online Access:http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472
Tags: Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
Journal Title:Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
Cite this:Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ.

Institution

Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
id irk-123456789-4472
record_format dspace
spelling irk-123456789-44722009-11-20T12:00:24Z Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market. 2007 Article Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ. 0321-3900 http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472 en Інститут математики НАН України
institution Digital Library of Periodicals of National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine
collection DSpace DC
language English
description We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has memory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market.
format Article
author Inoue, A.
Nakano, Y.
spellingShingle Inoue, A.
Nakano, Y.
Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
author_facet Inoue, A.
Nakano, Y.
author_sort Inoue, A.
title Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
title_short Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
title_full Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
title_fullStr Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
title_full_unstemmed Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
title_sort remark on optimal investment in a market with memory
publisher Інститут математики НАН України
publishDate 2007
url http://dspace.nbuv.gov.ua/handle/123456789/4472
citation_txt Remark on optimal investment in a market with memory / A. Inoue, Y. Nakano // Theory of Stochastic Processes. — 2007. — Т. 13 (29), № 1-2. — С. 66-76. — Бібліогр.: 18 назв.— англ.
work_keys_str_mv AT inouea remarkonoptimalinvestmentinamarketwithmemory
AT nakanoy remarkonoptimalinvestmentinamarketwithmemory
first_indexed 2025-07-02T07:42:34Z
last_indexed 2025-07-02T07:42:34Z
_version_ 1836520208895836160
fulltext Theory of Stochastic Processes Vol.13 (29), no.1-2, 2007, pp.66-76 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO REMARK ON OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY We consider a financial market model driven by a Gaussian semi- martingale with stationary increments. This driving noise process consists of n independent components and each component has mem- ory described by two parameters. We extend results of the authors on optimal investment in this market. 1. Introduction In this paper, we extend results of Inoue and Nakano [12] on optimal investment in a financial market model with memory. This market model M consists of n risky and one riskless assets. The price of the riskless asset is denoted by S0(t) and that of the ith risky asset by Si(t). We put S(t) = (S1(t), . . . , Sn(t)) ′, where A′ denotes the transpose of a matrix A. The dynamics of the Rn-valued process S(t) are described by the stochastic differential equation dSi(t) = Si(t) [ μi(t)dt + ∑n j=1 σij(t)dYj(t) ] , t ≥ 0, Si(0) = si, i = 1, . . . , n, (1) while those of S0(t) by the ordinary differential equation dS0(t) = r(t)S0(t)dt, t ≥ 0, S0(0) = 1, where the coefficients r(t) ≥ 0, μi(t), and σij(t) are continuous deterministic functions on [0,∞) and the initial prices si are positive constants. We assume that the n× n volatility matrix σ(t) = (σij(t))1≤i,j≤n is nonsingular for t ≥ 0. Invited lecture. 2000 Mathematics Subject Classifications. Primary 91B28, 60G10; Secondary 62P05, 93E20. Key words and phrases. Optimal investment, long term investment, processes with memory, processes with stationary increments, Riccati equations. 66 OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 67 We define the jth component Yj(t) of the Rn-valued driving noise process Y (t) = (Y1(t), . . . , Yn(t)) ′ of (1) by the autoregressive type equation dYj(t) dt = − ∫ t −∞ pje −qj(t−s) dYj(s) ds ds + dWj(t) dt , t ∈ R, Yj(0) = 0, where W (t) = (W1(t), . . . , Wn(t))′, t ∈ R, is an Rn-valued standard Brown- ian motion defined on a complete probability space (Ω,F , P ), the derivatives dYj(t)/dt and dWj(t)/dt are in the random distribution sense, and pj ’s and qj ’s are constants such that 0 < qj < ∞, −qj < pj < ∞, j = 1, . . . , n (2) (see Anh–Inoue [1]). Equivalently, we may define Yj(t) by the moving- average type representation Yj(t) = Wj(t) − ∫ t 0 [∫ s −∞ pje −(qj+pj)(s−u)dWj(u) ] ds, t ∈ R (see [1], Examples 2.12 and 2.14). The components Yj(t), j = 1, . . . , n, are Gaussian processes with stationary increments that are independent of each other. Each Yj(t) has short memory that is described by the two parameters pj and qj . Notice that, in the special case pj = 0, Yj(t) reduces to the Brownian motion Wj(t). The underlying information structure of the market model M is the filtration (Ft)t≥0 defined by Ft := σ (σ(Y (s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t) ∪N ) , t ≥ 0, where N is the P -null subsets of F . With respect to this filtration, Y (t) is a semimartingale. In fact, we have the following two kinds of semimartingale representations of Y (t) (see Anh et al. [2], Example 5.3, and Inoue et al. [13], Theorem 2.1): Yj(t) = Bj(t) − ∫ t 0 [∫ s 0 kj(s, u)dYj(u) ] ds, t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (3) Yj(t) = Bj(t) − ∫ t 0 [∫ s 0 lj(s, u)dBj(u) ] ds, t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (4) where, for j = 1, . . . , n, (Bj(t))t≥0 is the innovation process, i.e., an R- valued standard Brownian motion such that σ(Yj(s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t) = σ(Bj(s) : 0 ≤ s ≤ t), t ≥ 0, and Bj’s are independent of each other. The point of (3) and (4) is that the deterministic kernels kj(t, s) and lj(t, s) are given explicitly by kj(t, s) = pj(2qj + pj) (2qj + pj)e qjs − pje −qjs (2qj + pj)2eqjt − p2 je −qjt , 0 ≤ s ≤ t, (5) lj(t, s) = e−(pj+qj)(t−s)lj(s), 0 ≤ s ≤ t, (6) 68 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO with lj(s) := pj [ 1 − 2pjqj (2qj + pj)2e2qjs − p2 j ] , s ≥ 0. (7) There already exist many references in which the standard driving noise, that is, Brownian motion, is replaced by a different one, such as fractional Brownian motion, so that the market model can capture memory effect. See, e.g., Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [3], Hu et al. [11], Mishura [15] and Heyde and Leonenko [10]. Among such models, the above model M driven by Y (t) which is a Gaussian semimartingale with stationary increments is possibly the simplest one. One advantage of M is that, assuming σij(t) = σij , real constants, we can easily estimate the characteristic parameters pj, qj and σij from stock price data. See [12], Appendix C, for this parameter estimation from real market data. In the market M, an agent with initial endowment x ∈ (0,∞) invests, at each time t, πi(t)X x,π(t) dollars in the ith risky asset for i = 1, . . . , n and [1 − ∑n i=1 πi(t)]X x,π(t) dollars in the riskless asset, where Xx,π(t) denotes the agent’s wealth at time t. The wealth process Xx,π(t) is governed by the stochastic differential equation dXx,π(t) Xx,π(t) = [ 1 − ∑n i=1 πi(t) ] dS0(t) S0(t) + ∑n i=1 πi(t) dSi(t) Si(t) , Xx,π(0) = x. Here, the self-financing strategy π(t) = (π1(t), . . . , πn(t))′ is chosen from the admissible class AT := { π = (π(t))0≤t≤T : π is an Rn-valued, progressively measurable process satisfying ∫ T 0 ‖π(t)‖2dt < ∞ a.s. } for the finite time horizon of length T ∈ (0,∞), where ‖ · ‖ denotes the Euclidean norm of Rn. If the time horizon is infinite, π(t) is chosen from A := {(π(t))t≥0 : (π(t))0≤t≤T ∈ AT for every T ∈ (0,∞)} . Let α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and c ∈ R. In [12], the following three optimal investment problems for the model M are considered: V (T, α) := sup π∈AT 1 α E [(Xx,π(T ))α] , (8) J(α) := sup π∈A lim sup T→∞ 1 αT log E [(Xx,π(T ))α] , (9) I(c) := sup π∈A lim sup T→∞ 1 T log P [ Xx,π(T ) ≥ ecT ] . (10) Problem (8) is the classical optimal investment problem that dates back to Merton (cf. Karatzas and Shreve [14]). Hu et al. [11] studied this problem for OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 69 a Black–Scholes type model driven by fractional Brownian motion. Problem (9) is a kind of long term optimal investment problem which is studied by Bielecki and Pliska [4], and also by other authors under various settings, including Fleming and Sheu [5,6], Nagai and Peng [16], Pham [17,18], Hata and Iida [7], and Hata and Sekine [8,9]. Problem (10) is another type of long term optimal investment problem, the aim of which is to maximize the large deviation probability that the wealth grows at a higher rate than the given benchmark c. Pham [17,18] studied this problem and established a duality relation between Problems (9) and (10). Subsequently, this problem is studied by Hata and Iida [7] and Hata and Sekine [8,9] under different settings. In [12], Problems (8)–(10) are studied for the market model M which has memory. There, the following condition, rather than (2), is assumed in solving (8)–(10): 0 < qj < ∞, 0 ≤ pj < ∞, j = 1, . . . , n. (11) Thus, in [12], pj ≥ 0 rather than pj > −qj for j = 1, . . . , n. In this paper, we focus on Problems (8) and (9), and extends the results of [12] so that pj ’s may take negative values. The key to this extension is to show the existence of solution for a relevant Riccati type equation. In Sections 2 and 3, we review the results of [12] on Problems (8) and (9), respectively, and, in Section 4, we extend these results. 2. Optimal investment over a finite horizon In this section, we review the result of [12] on the finite horizon optimiza- tion problem (8) for the market model M. We assume α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and (11). Let Y (t) = (Y1(t), . . . , Yn(t)) ′ and B(t) = (B1(t), . . . , Bn(t))′ be the driv- ing noise and innovation processes, respectively, described in the previous section. We define an Rn-valued deterministic function λ(t) = (λ1(t), . . . , λn(t))′ by λ(t) := σ−1(t) [μ(t) − r(t)1] , t ≥ 0, (12) where 1 := (1, . . . , 1)′ ∈ Rn. For kj(t, s)’s in (5), we put k(t, s) := diag(k1(t, s), . . . , kn(t, s)), 0 ≤ s ≤ t. Let ξ(t) = (ξ1(t), . . . , ξn(t)) ′ be the Rn-valued process ∫ t 0 k(t, s)dY (s), i.e., ξj(t) := ∫ t 0 kj(t, s)dYj(s), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n. (13) Let β be the conjugate exponent of α, i.e., (1/α) + (1/β) = 1. 70 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO Notice that 0 < β < 1 (resp. −∞ < β < 0) if −∞ < α < 0 (resp. 0 < α < 1). We put l(t) := diag(l1(t), . . . , ln(t)), p := diag(p1, . . . , pn), and q := diag(q1, . . . , qn) with lj(t)’s as in (7). We also put ρ(t) = (ρ1(t), . . . , ρn(t))′, b(t) = diag(b1(t), . . . , bn(t)) with ρj(t) := −βlj(t)λj(t), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n, (14) bj(t) := −(pj + qj) + βlj(t), t ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , n. (15) We consider the following one-dimensional backward Riccati equations: for j = 1, . . . , n Ṙj(t) − l2j (t)R 2 j (t) + 2bj(t)Rj(t) + β(1 − β) = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T, Rj(T ) = 0. (16) We have the following result on the existence of solution to (16). Lemma 1 ([12], Lemma 2.1). Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. 1. If pj = 0, then (16) has a unique solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ). 2. If pj > 0 and −∞ < α < 0, then (16) has a unique nonnegative solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ). 3. If pj > 0 and 0 < α < 1, then (16) has a unique solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) such that Rj(t) ≥ bj(t)/l 2 j (t) for t ∈ [0, T ]. In what follows, we write Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) for the unique solution to (16) in the sense of Lemma 1, and we put R(t) := diag(R1(t), . . . , Rn(t)). For j = 1, . . . , n, let vj(t) ≡ vj(t; T ) be the solution to the following one-dimensional linear equation: v̇j(t) + [bj(t) − l2j (t)Rj(t; T )]vj(t) + β(1 − β)λj(t) − Rj(t; T )ρj(t) = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T, vj(T ) = 0. (17) We put v(t) ≡ v(t; T ) := (v1(t; T ), . . . , vn(t; T ))′. For j = 1, . . . , n and (t, T ) ∈ Δ, write gj(t; T ) := v2 j (t; T )l2j (t) + 2ρj(t)vj(t; T ) − l2j (t)Rj(t; T ) − β(1 − β)λ2 j(t), where Δ := {(t, T ) : 0 < T < ∞, 0 ≤ t ≤ T}. Recall that we have assumed α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and (11). Here is the solution to Problem (8) under the condition (11). OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 71 Theorem 2 ([12], Theorem 2.3). For T ∈ (0,∞), the strategy (π̂T (t))0≤t≤T ∈ AT defined by π̂T (t) := (σ′)−1(t) [(1 − β)λ(t) − {1 − β + l(t)R(t;T )}ξ(t) + l(t)v(t;T )] (18) is the unique optimal strategy for Problem (8). The value function V (T ) ≡ V (T, α) in (8) is given by V (T ) = 1 α [xS0(T )]α exp [ (1 − α) 2 ∑n j=1 ∫ T 0 gj(t; T )dt ] . 3. Optimal investment over an infinite horizon In this section, we review the result of [12] on the infinite horizon opti- mization problem (9) for the financial market model M. Throughout this section, we assume (11) and the following two conditions: lim T→∞ 1 T ∫ T 0 r(t)dt = r̄ with r̄ ∈ R, (19) lim T→∞ λ(t) = λ̄ with λ̄ = (λ̄1, . . . , λ̄n)′ ∈ Rn. (20) Here recall λ(t) = (λ1(t), . . . , λn(t))′ from (12). Let α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and β be its conjugate exponent. Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. For bj(t) in (15), we have limt→∞ bj(t) = b̄j , where b̄j := −(1 − β)pj − qj . Notice that b̄j < 0. We consider the equation p2 jx 2 − 2b̄jx − β(1 − β) = 0. (21) When pj = 0, we write R̄j for the unique solution β(1 − β)/(2qj) of this linear equation. If pj > 0, then b̄2 j + β(1 − β)p2 j = (1 − β)[(pj + qj) 2 − q2 j ] + q2 j ≥ q2 j > 0, so that we may write R̄j for the larger solution to the quadratic equation (21). Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. For ρj(t) in (14), we have limt→∞ ρj(t) = ρ̄j, where ρ̄j := −βpjλ̄j. Define v̄j by ( b̄j − p2 j R̄j ) v̄j + β(1 − β)λ̄j − R̄j ρ̄j = 0. 72 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO For j = 1, . . . , n and −∞ < α < 1, α = 0, we put Fj(α) := (pj + qj) 2λ̄2 jα [(1 − α)(pj + qj)2 + αpj(pj + 2qj)] , and Gj(α) := (pj + qj) − qjα −(1 − α)1/2 [(1 − α)(pj + qj) 2 + αpj(pj + 2qj)] 1/2 . Recall ξ(t) from (13). Taking into account (18), we consider π̂ = (π̂(t))t≥0 ∈ A defined by π̂(t) := (σ′)−1(t) [ (1 − β)λ(t) − (1 − β + pR̄)ξ(t) + pv̄ ] , t ≥ 0, where R̄ := diag(R̄1, . . . , R̄n), v̄ := (v̄1, . . . , v̄n)′, and p := diag(p1, . . . , pn). We define α∗ := max(α1∗, . . . , αn∗) (22) with αj∗ := { −∞ if −∞ < pj ≤ 2qj, −3 − 8qj pj−2qj if 2qj < pj < ∞. (23) Notice that α∗ ∈ [−∞,−3). Recall that we have assumed (11), (19) and (20). Here is the solution to Problem (9) under the condition (11). Theorem 3 ([12], Theorem 3.4). Let α∗ < α < 1, α = 0. Then π̂ is an optimal strategy for Problem (9) with limit rather than limsup in (9). The optimal growth rate J(α) in (9) is given by J(α) = r̄ + 1 2α n∑ j=1 Fj(α) + 1 2α n∑ j=1 Gj(α). 4. Extensions In this section, we extend Theorems 2 and 3 so that pj’s may take negative values. The key is to extend Lemma 1 properly. We assume α ∈ (−∞, 1) \ {0} and (2). We put, for j = 1, . . . , n, a1j(t) = lj(t) 2, a2j(t) = βlj(t) − (pj + qj), a3 = β(1 − β). OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 73 Then the Riccati equation (16) becomes Ṙj(t) − a1j(t)R 2 j (t) + 2a2j(t)Rj(t) + a3 = 0, 0 ≤ t ≤ T, Rj(T ) = 0. Note that lj(t) is increasing and satisfies lj(0) = pj(pj + 2qj) 2(pj + qj) ≤ lj(t) ≤ pj , t ≥ 0. Proposition 4. Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and 0 < α ≤ ( pj + qj pj + qj − lj(0) )2 . (24) 1. It holds that a2j(t) ≤ 0 for t ≥ 0. 2. It holds that a2j(t) 2 + a1j(t)a3 ≥ 0 for t ≥ 0. Proof. We have a2j(t) = βlj(t) − (pj + qj) ≤ βlj(0) − (pj + qj), whence a2j(t) ≤ 0 if β ≥ (pj + qj)/lj(0) or α ≤ (pj + qj)/lj(0) [(pj + qj)/lj(0)] − 1 = pj + qj pj + qj − lj(0) . However, 0 < (pj + qj)/[pj + qj − lj(0)] < 1, whence pj + qj pj + qj − lj(0) > ( pj + qj pj + qj − lj(0) )2 . Thus the first assertion follows. We have a2j(t) 2 + a1j(t)a3 = βlj(t) 2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(t)β + (pj + qj) 2 ≥ βlj(0)2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(0)β + (pj + qj) 2 = β[{(pj + qj) − lj(0)}2 − (pj + qj) 2] + (pj + qj) 2, whence a2j(t) 2 + a1j(t)a3 ≥ 0 if β ≥ (pj + qj) 2 (pj + qj)2 − [(pj + qj) − lj(0)]2 . However, this is equivalent to α ≤ [(pj + qj)/{pj + qj − lj(0)}]2. Thus the second assertion follows. Lemma 5. Let j ∈ {1, . . . , n}. 74 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO 1. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and −∞ < α < 0. Then (16) has a unique nonnegative solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ). 2. We assume −qj < pj < 0 and (24). Then (16) has a unique solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) such that Rj(t) ≥ R∗ j (t) for t ∈ [0, T ], where R∗ j (t) := a2j(t) + √ a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3 a1j(t) . Proof. The first assertion follows in the same way as in the proof of [12], Lemma 2.1 (ii). Thus we prove the second assertion. Notice that R∗ j (t) is the larger solution to the quadratic equation a1j(t)x 2 − 2a2j(t)x − a3 = 0. Thus a1j(t)R ∗ j (t) 2 − 2a2j(t)R ∗ j (t) − a3 = 0. (25) Since a1j(t) > 0, a2j(t) ≤ 0 and a3 < 0, we see that R∗ j (t) ≤ 0. The equation for V (t) := Rj(t) − R∗ j (t) becomes V̇ (t) − a1j(t)V (t)2 + 2[a2j(t) − a1j(t)R ∗ j (t)]V (t) + Ṙ∗ j (t) = 0. (26) By differenciating (25), we get ȧ1j(t)R ∗ j (t) 2 + 2a1j(t)R ∗ j (t)Ṙ ∗ j (t) − 2ȧ2jR ∗ j (t) − 2a2j(t)Ṙ ∗ j (t) = 0, whence Ṙ∗ j (t) = 2ȧ2j(t)R ∗ j (t) − ȧ1j(t)R ∗(t)2 2 √ a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3 . Now 2ȧ2j(t)R ∗ j (t) − ȧ1jR ∗ j (t) 2 = −2l̇j(t)R ∗ j (t){lj(t)R∗ j (t) − β}. Since a2j(t) 2 + a1j(t)a3 = βlj(t) 2 − 2(pj + qj)lj(t)β + (pj + qj) 2 < (pj + qj) 2, we see that lj(t)R ∗ j (t) − β = 1 lj(t) [ −(pj + qj) + √ a2j(t)2 + a1j(t)a3 ] > 0. Thus Ṙ∗ j (t) ≥ 0. This and a1j(t) > 0 imply that (26) has a unique nonneg- ative solution. The second assertion follows from this. We define α∗ := min(α∗ 1, . . . , α ∗ n) OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN A MARKET WITH MEMORY 75 with α∗ j := { ( pj+qj pj+qj−lj(0) )2 if − qj < pj < 0, 1 if 0 ≤ pj < ∞. Notice that α∗ ∈ (0, 1]. Recall α∗ from (22). Taking the solution Rj(t) ≡ Rj(t; T ) of (16) in the sense of Lemma 1 or 5 and running through the same arguments as those in [12], Sections 2 and 3, we obtain the following extensions to Theorems 2 and 3. Theorem 6. We assume (2) and −∞ < α < α∗, α = 0. Then the same conclusions as those of Theorem 2 hold. Theorem 7. We assume (2), (19), (20) and α∗ < α < α∗, α = 0. Then the same conclusions as those of Theorem 3 hold. Bibliography 1. Anh, V. and Inoue, A., Financial markets with memory I: Dynamic models, Stoch. Anal. Appl., 23, (2005), 275–300. 2. Anh, V., Inoue, A. and Kasahara, Y., Financial markets with memory II: Innovation processes and expected utility maximization, Stoch. Anal. Appl., 23, (2005), 301–328. 3. Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N., Non-Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlen- beck-based models and some of their uses in financial economics, J. Roy. Statist. Soc. Ser. B, 63, (2001), 167–241. 4. Bielecki, T. R. and Pliska, S. R., Risk sensitive dynamic asset management, Appl. Math. Optim., 39, (1999), 337–360. 5. Fleming W. H. and Sheu, S. J., Risk-sensitive control and an optimal in- vestment model, Math. Finance, 10, (2000), 197–213. 6. Fleming, W. H. and Sheu, S. J., Risk-sensitive control and an optimal investment model (II), Ann. Appl. Probab., 12, (2000), 730–767. 7. Hata, H. and Iida, Y., A risk-sensitive stochastic control approach to an optimal investment problem with partial information, Finance Stoch., 10, (2006), 395–426. 8. Hata, H. and Sekine, J., Solving long term optimal investment problems with Cox-Ingersoll-Ross interest rates, Adv. Math. Econ., 8, (2006), 231– 255. 9. Hata, H. and Sekine, J., Solving a large deviations control problem with a nonlinear factor model, preprint. 10. Heyde, C. C. and Leonenko, N. N., Student processes, Adv. in Appl. Probab., 37, (2005), 342–365. 11. Hu, Y. Øksendal, B. and Sulem, A., Optimal consumption and portfolio in a Black-Scholes market driven by fractional Brownian motion, Infin. Dimens. Anal. Quantum Probab. Relat. Top., 6, (2003), 519–536. 76 AKIHIKO INOUE AND YUMIHARU NAKANO 12. Inoue, A. and Nakano, Y., Optimal long term investment model with mem- ory, Appl. Math. Optim., to appear. Available at http://arxiv.org/abs/math.PR/0506621. 13. Inoue, A. Nakano, Y. and Anh, V., Linear filtering of systems with memory and application to finance, J. Appl. Math. Stoch. Anal., 2006, (2006), 1–26. 14. Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S. E., Methods of mathematical finance, Springer- Verlag, New York, (1998). 15. Mishura, Yu., Fractional stochastic integration and Black–Scholes equa- tion for fractional Brownian motion model with stochastic volatility, Stoch. Stoch. Rep., 76, (2004), 363–381. 16. Nagai, H. and Peng, S., Risk-sensitive dynamic portfolio optimization with partial information on infinite time horizon, Ann. Appl. Probab., 12, (2002), 173–195. 17. Pham, H., A large deviations approach to optimal long term investment, Finance Stoch., 7, (2003), 169–195. 18. Pham, H., A risk-sensitive control dual approach to a large deviations con- trol problem, Systems Control Lett., 49, (2003), 295–309. Department of Mathematics, Faculty of Science, Hokkaido Univer- sity, Sapporo 060-0810, Japan. E-mail address: inoue@math.sci.hokudai.ac.jp Center for the Study of Finance and Insurance, Osaka University, Toyonaka 560-8531, Japan. E-mail address: y-nakano@sigmath.es.osaka-u.ac.jp